Tuesday, March 31, 2020

1151 Dr H. C. Coombs on Central Banking, Wartime Finance, and Monetary Policy in Australia

Dr H. C. Coombs on Central Banking, Wartime Finance, and Monetary Policy
in Australia

Newsletter published on March 28, 2020

This material, and more on Coombs, is at http://mailstar.net/coombs.html  .

Dr H. C. "Nugget" Coombs was Governor of Australia's publicly-owned
Commonwealth Bank (from 1960 renamed the Reserve Bank of Australia) from
1949 to 1968, when I was growing up; his signature was on all of our
bank notes.

He helped create our leading University (ANU), and was later its Chancellor.

He led the campaign for a treaty between Aboriginal and non-Aboriginal
Australia. Aborigines nicknamed him "short father".

But Coombs also advocated Free Trade - as he says in his book Trial
Balance - which has undone the Full Employment policy he had espoused.

Subsequent to that article (1974), he produced a report for the Whitlam
Government whose implementation has ruined Rural Australia, and created
the Welfare State which has destroyed family life and disrupted the
transmission of Aboriginal Culture.

Gough Whitlam, Prime Minister from 1972-5, reveals that it was Nugget
Coombs who was behind the 25% drop in tariffs Whitlam implemented.

The material below, and more on Coombs, is at

Other People's Money

by H. C. Coombs

Australian National University Press, Canberra 1971

The English, Scottish and Australian Bank Research Lecture, University
of Queensland, 15 September 1954. Reproduced by permission of the
University of Queensland Press.

{p. 9} The Development of Monetary Policy in Australia

THERE has been in recent years a change in the attitude towards monetary
policy. Most of us can remember when anything which had anything to do
with money was both in the mediaeval and modem sense of the term
something of a mystery; an activity carried on by an exclusive group
behind closed doors.

In these times almost anybody is prepared to express views on monetary
and banking policy - some of them less well-informed than they might be.
Although those responsible for monetary policy act in the light of the
fullest knowledge available, and I believe with a high sense of
responsibility, it is important that monetary as well as other economic
problems should be the subject of analysis and discussion.

The mystery element in monetary policy was sharply reduced with the
emergence of what has been described as the 'Keynesian Revolution' in
economics. The Keynesian analysis of the economic system provided the
means by which the effects of monetary policy could be assessed. The
essence of the Keynesian analysis was that in a market economy the level
of production and employment is determined by the level of spending;
spending by households, by firms and businesses, and by public
authorities and government. And consequently it followed that there is a
level of spending which is sufficient to employ the whole of the labour
and available resources of the economy. If spending falls short of that
level the economy will experience unemployment and resources will be
idle. On the other hand, if spending exceeds that level, since output
and employment can be increased no further, the increased spending will
show itself in rising prices and shortages of goods, labour, and materials.

This over-simplified version of the Keynesian analysis brings out the
significance of spending on employment and production and thereby
provides us with a criterion by which monetary policy can be tested.
What will be the effect of a given policy on spending? Would such an

{p. 10} effect be appropriate in the current condition of employment and
production?

Any given piece of expenditure can be financed from one of four sources
(or a combination of these sources):

(1) new savings;

(2) accumulated reserves;

(3) money borrowed, other than from a bank;

(4) money borrowed from a bank.

The last source differs from the first three because when money is lent
by a bank it passes into the hands of the person who borrows it without
anybody having less. Whenever a bank lends money there is, therefore, an
increase in the total amount of money available.

Spending can be influenced by the amount of money which is available in
a community and also by the freedom with which people will draw upon
their stocks of money to spend or lend. It can be influenced also by the
willingness of banks to lend. Since monetary policy can influence both
the supply of money and the willingness of banks to lend, and
consequently the total volume of spending, there is a close connection
between the monetary policy and levels of employment and production.
Monetary policy can be examined, either in prospect or retrospect, by
tracing its effects on spending, production, and employment and judging
whether these effects are appropriate to current circumstances.

Monetary policy is not good or bad in itself. Almost any form of
monetary action can be justified in some circumstances and can be
utterly wrong in others. For instance, I can remember when people used
to get very agitated about a central bank lending to its government.
Such loans, like any other form of monetary action, are good or bad
according to the circumstances in which they are made. We must beware of
an approach to monetary policy in terms of rigid rules. The test of
monetary policy is in its effects.

With these things in mind we can turn to the development of monetary
policy in Australia over the last few decades. It is an interesting
thing that the first result of the emergence of the Keynesian analysis
was rather to push monetary policy as such into the background. For a
while it came to be regarded as purely incidental to public expenditure
policy and consequently as having little initiative of itself. This
tendency arose largely from the conviction that grew out of the
depression of the 1930s, that there was an inherent tendency in a market
economy for expenditure to be insufficient to sustain employment and
production. If this conviction were true, monetary policy became simply
the means to increase expenditure - a task in which the initiative
needed should properly be with governments, businesses, and individuals;
the banking system acting as the responsive servant of governments and

{p. 11} of industry to provide finance as calle;d upon. In a period of
substantial under-employment of resources is was perhaps not an
unreasonable over-simplification. It was clear that almost anything
which increased the level of expenditure would overall have desirable
effects. In such a situation monetary policy inevitably came to be
looked on as a secondary and rather passive instrument of economic policy.

The war pushed monetary policy even further into the background. The
economic problem of the war was to divert the physical and human
resources of the economy to the greatest possible extent to activities
associated wit e war. Such a diversion, once resources were fully
employed, required the withdrawal of resources away from other
activities. In financial sense these two aspects of wartime policy were
reflected tremendous expenditure by government, and by measures to
restrict expenditure by all other persons, firms and authorities which
might require the production of goods not strictly necessary for war
purposes. The government's military expenditure was financed from the
proceeds of taxes and public loans but also by borrowing from the
Central Bank. Measures to restrict other expenditure included taxation
and loan raising but also a variety of more direct limitations. By
rationing and by various forms of control people were prevented from
spending. Furthermore, price control was imposed on the whole range of
goods available so that the amount of money which could be spent on
civil goods was limited. As a result people and businesses found they
earned far more money than they could spend even after taxes, and there
was steadily built up a large accumulation of deposits in the banks and
of notes in the hands of the public. By the end of the war, the volume
of money was 120 per cent higher than it had been at the outbreak of the
war. Thus throughout the war the role of the monetary authority was the
largely passive one of providing the financial needs of government to
the extent that these could not be met from taxes and public loans, and
the task of limiting other forms of expenditure and restraining the
inflationary tendencies inherent in this form of finance was undertaken
primarily by the government through direct controls. [...]

Keep reading at at http://mailstar.net/coombs.html  .

No comments:

Post a Comment

Note: Only a member of this blog may post a comment.