Investment Treaties & TPP: instruments of Empire by 1%
Newsletter published on 18 November 2013
(1) Investment
Treaties & TPP: instruments of Empire by 1%
(2) TPP puts Companies above
Governments; it's World Empire, the
opposite of World Government - Paul
Craig Roberts
(3) TPP favours offshore data centres, raising Snowden/NSA
surveillance
concerns
(4) Countries turn against Investment agreements:
South Africa Breaks
Out, by Joseph Stiglitz
(5) Protectionist Economists
defy Free Trade dogma - Eamonn Fingleton
(6) Obituary: John M. Culbertson,
economist who defended Protectionism
(7) U.S. 'Free Trade' with Mexico, by
John Culbertson
(1) Investment Treaties & TPP: instruments of Empire
by 1%
Gary G. Kohls <gkohls@cpinternet.com> 8 November
2013 06:12
The item below comes from my internet whistle-blower friend
Peter Tocci,
of the Boston area, who has a keen eye for corporate and
governmental
corruption, military misadventures and malfeasance of all
types.
He writes about the TransPacific Partnership, which was well
exposed on
Bill Moyers’ November 1, 2013 show, entitled, the “Top Secret
Trade Deal
You Need to Know About” and which is archived at:
http://billmoyers.com/episode/full-show-the-top-secret-trade-deal-you-need-to-know-about/
Peter
says: “If you need further evidence of the global
fascist/surveillance
state, see this piece (from Nation of Change at:
http://www.nationofchange.org/trash-tpp-why-its-time-revolt-against-worst-trade-agreement-history-1374584845)
on the "TPP," a 'trade agreement' now being secretly negotiated due
its nasty ramifications. A small taste:
Some of the most heinous
parts of the TPP are provisions to set up
rigged trade tribunals. In these
tribunals, corporations can sue
governments for the loss of “expected future
profits.” This means that
if a country passes an environmental or a health
law that will cost the
corporation money, the corporation can sue for the
expected profits it
stands to lose. The suit will come before a trade
tribunal where a
three-judge panel, made up mostly of corporate lawyers on
temporary
leave from their corporate jobs, will decide the case.
The
takeaway from the tribunals is this: they will dissuade countries
from
putting in place public interest laws because those governments
will be sued
and forced to pay millions to corporations. We've already
experienced
something like this, though on a less sweeping scale. Global
Trade Watch
reports that under previous trade agreements, “over $3
billion has been paid
to foreign investors under US trade and investment
pacts, while over $14
billion in claims are pending under such deals,
primarily targeting
environmental, energy, and public health policies.”
By the end of 2011,
corporations like Chevron, Exxon Mobil, Dow
Chemical, and Cargill had
launched 450 investor-state cases against 89
governments, including the US,
to fight regulations that protect the
environment. Among these cases were
bans of toxic chemicals,
hydrofracking, timber and mining regulations, and
programs that
incentivized green jobs and renewable energy
programs.
http://www.nationofchange.org/trash-tpp-why-its-time-revolt-against-worst-trade-agreement-history-1374584845
Here
is Peter’s comment:.
In fact, the 'expected future profits' scam is
already a part of "free
trade." It's easier to see the scams when you know
the central principle
behind the Elite MO: Things done to advance the Agenda
are always
presented as 'good' for us or for the country. Or a necessary
evil at
worst. Anything advanced to 'solve' a major problem, most of which
are
created or lied about, should be automatically suspect and fully
scrutinized. For some reason, the Illuminati fear widespread awareness
of their game. Their control of the news media is strong evidence of
this. Of course, the media is also used to program the mass mind and
reinforce self-defeating belief systems.
(2) TPP puts Companies above
Governments; it's World Empire, the
opposite of World Government - Paul
Craig Roberts
http://www.foreignpolicyjournal.com/2012/07/04/trans-pacific-partnership-corporate-escape-from-accountability
Trans
Pacific Partnership: Corporate Escape from Accountability
by Paul Craig
Roberts
July 4, 2012
Information has been leaked about the Trans
Pacific Partnership, which
is being negotiated in secret by US Trade
Representative Ron Kirk. Six
hundred corporate “advisors” are in on the
know, but not Congress or the
media. Ron Wyden, chairman of the Senate
trade subcommittee that has
jurisdiction over the TPP, has not been
permitted to see the text or to
know the content.
The TPP has been
called a “one-percenter” power tool. The agreement
essentially abolishes the
accountability of foreign corporations to
governments of countries with
which they trade. Indeed, the agreement
makes governments accountable to
corporations for costs imposed by
regulations, including health, safety and
environmental regulations. The
agreement gives corporations the right to
make governments pay them for
the cost of complying with the regulations of
government. One wonders
how long environmental, labor, and financial
regulation can survive when
the costs of compliance are imposed on the
taxpayers of countries and
not on the economic activity that results in
spillover effects such as
pollution.
Many will interpret the TPP as
another big step toward the establishment
of global government in the New
World Order. However, what the TPP
actually does is to remove corporations
or the spillover effects of
their activities from the reach of government.
As the TPP does not
transfer to corporations the power to govern countries,
it is difficult
to see how it leads to global government. The real result is
global
privilege of the corporate class as a class immune to government
regulation.
One of the provisions allows corporations to avoid the courts
and laws
of countries by creating a private tribunal that corporations can
use to
sue governments for the costs of complying with regulation.
Essentially, the laws of countries that apply to corporations are
supplanted by decisions of a private tribunal of corporate
lawyers.
The TPP is open to all countries. Currently, it is being
negotiated
between the US, Australia, Brunei, New Zealand, Singapore,
Vietnam,
Chile, and Peru. Australia, according to reports, has refused to
submit
to the private tribunal system.
What are we to make of the
TPP? It is perhaps too early to have all the
answers. However, I can offer
some ways of thinking about it.
I doubt that the TPP is a New World Order
takeover. If anything, the TPP
reduces the scope of global government by
exempting corporations from
government control. Also, global government,
unless it is government by
the American Empire, is inconsistent with the
neoconservative insistence
on US hegemony over the world. Powerful US
ideological, private, and
government interest groups have no intention of
losing the power that
they have acquired by being rolled into some New World
Order unless the
New World Order is a euphemism for American
Empire.
In the criticisms of the TPP, much emphasis is placed on the
costs that
corporations of foreign members of the agreement can impose on
the US.
However, US corporations gain the same privileges over those
countries,
as the agreement gives every country’s corporations immunity to
the
other countries’ laws.
It could be the case that US corporations
believe that their penetration
of the other countries will greatly exceed
the activities in the US of
Brunei, New Zealand, Peru, et al. However, once
Japan, Canada, China
and others join TPP, the prospect of American firms
getting more out of
the agreement than foreign firms disappears, unless from
the US
perspective the definition of foreign firm includes US corporations
that
offshore the production of the goods and services that they market in
the US. If this is the case, then US offshoring firms would be exempt
not only from the laws and courts of foreign countries, but also exempt
from the laws and courts of the US.
This point is possibly moot as
the agreement requires all governments
that are parties to the TPP to
harmonize their laws so that the new
corporate privileges are equally
reflected in every country. To avoid
discriminatory law against a country’s
own corporations that do not
engage in foreign trade, harmonization could
mean that domestic
corporations would be granted the same privileges as
foreign investors.
If not, domestic firms might acquire the privileges by
setting up a
foreign subsidiary consisting of an office.
As the TPP
is clearly an agreement being pushed by US corporations, the
implication is
that US corporations see it as being to their relative
advantage. However,
it is unclear what this advantage is.
Alternatively, TPP is a strategy
for securing exemption from regulation
under the guise of being a trade
agreement.
Another explanation, judging from the unusual collection of
the initial
parties to the agreement, is that the agreement is part of
Washington’s
strategy of encircling China with military bases, as the US has
done to
Russia. One would have thought that an agreement of such
path-breaking
nature would have begun with Japan, S. Korea, and the
Philippines.
However, these countries are already part of China’s
encirclement.
Brunei, Singapore, New Zealand, and especially Vietnam would
be valuable
additions. Are the special privileges that Washington is
offering these
countries part of the bribe to become de facto outposts of
American Empire?
Yet another explanation is that Ron Kirk is caught up in
the
deregulatory mindset that began with the repeal of Glass-Steagall and
financial deregulation. If financial markets know best and are
self-regulating, requiring no government interference, then so also are
other markets and businesses. [Editor’s note: Glass-Steagall was not
repealed in full; the separation in the Glass-Steagall Act of
commercial
from investment banking was repealed while the Federal
Deposit Insurance was
not, meaning that taxpayers would ultimately be on
the hook for any risky
activities of the banks necessitating bailouts.]
Some ‘free market’
economists view regulations as “takings.” The
argument is that regulations
take corporate property—profits, for
example, by making corporations comply
with health, safety, and
environmental regulation—just as government takes
private property when
it builds or widens a road. Therefore, corporations
should be
compensated for takings that result from regulation. As the
argument
goes, if government wants corporations to protect the environment,
the
government should pay the corporations for the cost of doing so. This
argument gets rid of “external costs” or “social costs”—costs that
corporations impose on others and future generations by the pollution
and exhaustion of natural resources, for example. The argument turns
social costs into compensation for takings.
The TPP is likely serving
many agendas. As we learn more, the motives
behind the TPP will become
clearer. From my perspective as an economist
and former member of
government, the problem with Ron Kirk’s TPP is that
the agreement is
constructed to serve private, not public interests.
Kirk is a public
official charged with serving and protecting the public
interest. Yet, he
has conspired in secret with private interests to
produce a document that
exempts private corporations from public
accountability.
There is a
paradox here. While financial corporations and now all
corporations are
being made independent of government, US citizens have
lost the protection
of law and are now subject to being detained
indefinitely or murdered
without due process of law. Corporations gain
an unimaginable freedom while
citizens lose all freedom and the rights
that define their freedom.
Similarly, foreign countries, which as
members of TPP can be exempt from US
law, are subject to “pre-emptive”
US violation of their air space and
borders by drones and troops sent in
to assassinate some suspected
terrorist, but which also kill citizens of
those countries who are merely
going about their normal business.
Perhaps one way to understand TPP is
that the US government is now
extending its own right to be lawless to
corporations. Just as the US
government today is only answerable to itself,
the TPP makes
corporations answerable only to themselves.
Public
Citizen’s analysis of TPP can be found here and the leaked
document
here.
This article was originally published at PaulCraigRoberts.org and
has
been used here with permission.
(3) TPP favours offshore data
centres, raising Snowden/NSA surveillance
concerns
http://www.afr.com/p/technology/dark_cloud_over_privacy_in_tpp_negotiations_7MpUMeN49FgHTuvCDQScKN
Dark
cloud over privacy in TPP negotiations
PUBLISHED: 05 NOV 2013 00:05:18 |
UPDATED: 05 NOV 2013 00:07:13
JAMES HUTCHINSON
The secretive
Trans-Pacific Partnership agreement is heading towards a
privacy row, after
it emerged that organisations could be prevented from
mandating that
personal and critical data be kept within Australia.
The multilateral
treaty, under negotiation by 12 Pacific Rim countries
including Australia
and the United States, includes provisions that
prohibit states from
mandating where companies store or transact data.
Privacy experts say
that, if ratified, the provision would mean that
Australian government
agencies and major enterprises would not be able
to ensure personal and
private data is stored in onshore data centres.
“Trans-border data flows
have been subject to protections since about
1980; it’s always been
recognised that any country has got to be able to
exercise judgment on
behalf of its citizens in order to provide
protections against data flow
into places where that data will be abused
.?.?. the United States being one
of those countries,” said Roger
Clarke, chair of the Australian Privacy
Foundation.
“The idea that any country should give up on that and say
‘We’re
citizens of the world now; we don’t believe in privacy any more’:
that’s
a completely unacceptable position to adopt.”
Australian
negotiators say they and other member countries are pushing
against the
provision, first introduced by the United States. They
specifically want to
include exemptions in the treaty to keep existing
Australian health and
privacy laws, which forbid some data being stored
or transmitted
offshore.
The state of the provision, however, is unclear due to the
overt secrecy
of the TPP negotiations, a point of criticism for many
stakeholders.
Electronic Frontiers Australia executive officer Jon
Lawrence said the
push to restrict data sovereignty laws through the TPP was
largely a
commercial one, in a bid to keep US-based cloud service providers
such
as Google and e-commerce giant Amazon as major online storage
providers.
Such providers have lobbied Australian enterprises and government
agencies to drop restrictions on offshoring data but, at the same time,
have established their own local data centres to win millions of dollars
worth of storage and computing contracts for critical data.
A former
US ambassador to Australia, Jeffrey Bleich, championed the TPP
provisions
last year, citing the need to end “cloud protectionism”.
“In Australia,
such restrictions would undermine the economic benefits
the [national
broadband network] would deliver by cutting off access to
the highest
quality, lowest price and most secure cloud services for
businesses,
government and consumers,” he said at the time. “While some
local providers
may get a windfall, everyone else would lose out.”
He said arguments that
local data centres would provide better
protection from surveillance and
hacking were futile due to the global
nature of the internet. “Like keeping
money under the mattress, keeping
data ‘at home’ not only deprives you of
all the benefits the global
cloud offers, but it is probably far less safe
as well,” he said.
But recent revelations surrounding US surveillance
programs and
infiltration of ongoing monitoring of data transmitted to
Google and
Yahoo! have exacerbated concerns over whether individuals and
companies
should store data within national borders or wherever is most
convenient.
A survey for the Office of the Australian Information
Commissioner found
79 per cent of people surveyed thought companies
offshoring private data
a misuse of their information.
Mr Lawrence
said: “The whole NSA thing really becomes an own goal in
that perspective
because it’s pushing straight back against it. “There’s
a genuine risk, and
there’s already .?.?. evidence that people are
voting with their feet and
are going to move away from these US
companies because they don’t trust
what’s going on.”
(4) Countries turn against Investment agreements: South
Africa Breaks
Out, by Joseph Stiglitz
http://www.social-europe.eu/2013/11/south-africa-breaks-out/
South
Africa Breaks Out
07/11/2013
by Joseph
Stiglitz
International investment agreements are once again in the news.
The
United States is trying to impose a strong investment pact within the
two big so-called “partnership” agreements, one bridging the Atlantic,
the other the Pacific, that are now being negotiated. But there is
growing opposition to such moves.
South Africa has decided to stop
the automatic renewal of investment
agreements that it signed in the early
post-apartheid period, and has
announced that some will be terminated.
Ecuador and Venezuela have
already terminated theirs. India says that it
will sign an investment
agreement with the US only if the dispute-resolution
mechanism is
changed. For its part, Brazil has never had one at
all.
There is good reason for the resistance. Even in the US, labor
unions
and environmental, health, development, and other nongovernmental
organizations have objected to the agreements that the US is
proposing.
The agreements would significantly inhibit the ability of
developing
countries’ governments to protect their environment from mining
and
other companies; their citizens from the tobacco companies that
knowingly purvey a product that causes death and disease; and their
economies from the ruinous financial products that played such a large
role in the 2008 global financial crisis. They restrict governments even
from placing temporary controls on the kind of destabilizing short-term
capital flows that have so often wrought havoc in financial markets and
fueled crises in developing countries. Indeed, the agreements have been
used to challenge government actions ranging from debt restructuring to
affirmative action.
Advocates of such agreements claim that they are
needed to protect
property rights. But countries like South Africa already
have strong
constitutional guarantees of property rights. There is no reason
that
foreign-owned property should be better protected than property owned
by
a country’s own citizens.
Moreover, if constitutional guarantees
are not enough to convince
investors of South Africa’s commitment to
protecting property rights,
foreigners can always avail themselves of
expropriation insurance
provided by the Multilateral Investment Guarantee
Agency (a division of
the World Bank) or numerous national organizations
providing such
insurance. (Americans, for example, can buy insurance from
the Overseas
Private Investment Corporation.)
But those supporting
the investment agreements are not really concerned
about protecting property
rights, anyway. The real goal is to restrict
governments’ ability to
regulate and tax corporations – that is, to
restrict their ability to impose
responsibilities, not just uphold
rights. Corporations are attempting to
achieve by stealth – through
secretly negotiated trade agreements – what
they could not attain in an
open political process.
Even the notion
that this is about protecting foreign firms is a ruse:
companies based in
country A can set up a subsidiary in country B to sue
country A’s
government. American courts, for example, have consistently
ruled that
corporations need not be compensated for the loss of profits
from a change
in regulations (a so-called regulatory taking); but, under
the typical
investment agreement, a foreign firm (or an American firm,
operating through
a foreign subsidiary) can demand compensation!
Worse, investment
agreements enable companies to sue the government over
perfectly sensible
and just regulatory changes – when, say, a cigarette
company’s profits are
lowered by a regulation restricting the use of
tobacco. In South Africa, a
firm could sue if it believes that its
bottom line might by harmed by
programs designed to address the legacy
of official racism.
There is
a long-standing presumption of “sovereign immunity”: states can
be sued only
under limited circumstances. But investment agreements like
those backed by
the US demand that developing countries waive this
presumption and permit
the adjudication of suits according to procedures
that fall far short of
those expected in twenty-first-century
democracies. Such procedures have
proved to be arbitrary and capricious,
with no systemic way to reconcile
incompatible rulings issued by
different panels. While proponents argue that
investment treaties reduce
uncertainty, the ambiguities and conflicting
interpretations of these
agreements’ provisions have increased
uncertainty.
Countries that have signed such investment agreements have
paid a high
price. Several have been subject to enormous suits – and
enormous
payouts. There have even been demands that countries honor
contracts
signed by previous non-democratic and corrupt governments, even
when the
International Monetary Fund and other multilateral organizations
have
recommended that the contract be abrogated.
Even when
developing-country governments win the suits (which have
proliferated
greatly in the last 15 years), the litigation costs are
huge. The (intended)
effect is to chill governments’ legitimate efforts
to protect and advance
citizens’ interests by imposing regulations,
taxation, and other
responsibilities on corporations.
Moreover, for developing countries that
were foolish enough to sign such
agreements, the evidence is that the
benefits, if any, have been scant.
In South Africa’s review, it found that
it had not received significant
investments from the countries with which it
had signed agreements, but
had received significant investments from those
with which it had not.
It is no surprise that South Africa, after a
careful review of
investment treaties, has decided that, at the very least,
they should be
renegotiated. Doing so is not anti-investment; it is
pro-development.
And it is essential if South Africa’s government is to
pursue policies
that best serve the country’s economy and
citizens.
Indeed, by clarifying through domestic legislation the
protections
offered to investors, South Africa is once again demonstrating –
as it
has repeatedly done since the adoption of its new Constitution in 1996
–
its commitment to the rule of law. It is the investment agreements
themselves that most seriously threaten democratic
decision-making.
South Africa should be congratulated. Other countries,
one hopes, will
follow suit.
(5) Protectionist Economists defy Free
Trade dogma - Eamonn Fingleton
http://www.fingleton.net/?p=1143
Beyond
free trade
Posted on April 13, 2011 by Eamonn Fingleton
Meet the
heterodox economists challenging globalism. (This article was
first
published in the April 2011 issue of the American Conservative.)
"I don't
care who writes a nation's laws, or crafts its advanced
treatises, if I can
write its economics textbooks." So said one of the
greatest textbook writers
of them all, Paul Samuelson.
But even Samuelson didn't live forever—he
died in 2009 aged 94—and now
others decide what the rising generation is
reading. It is a fair bet
that, on one of the most critical issues of modern
economic policy, his
successors' books would not meet with the master's
approval. That issue
is trade.
Although Samuelson spent most of his
life promoting unqualified free
trade, he came close in his declining years
to admitting he was wrong.
In a paper in 2004, he suggested that there might
be some circumstances
in which a nation did not benefit from free trade. His
analysis was
carefully hedged; but, given his unique status not only as a
textbook
writer but as the first American economist to win a Nobel Prize,
the
effect on the faithful was as if the pope had conceded there might not
be a God after all.
The interesting thing is that Samuelson's doubts
have not merited so
much as a footnote in most of today's top selling
textbooks. This is not
an isolated oversight. The textbooks have overlooked
many other key
developments, not least the work of Ralph Gomory and William
Baumol, who
have posited a much more widely applicable, if equally
mathematically
watertight, challenge to conventional trade theory. These
omissions are
all the more surprising for the fact that economics textbooks
are
constantly revised and updated, the better no doubt to keep sales
ticking.
Robert Prasch, an economic historian at Middlebury College and a
prominent critic of the free-trade consensus, puts it succinctly: "The
economics profession generally is probably 15 years behind reality, and
the textbook writers are a further 15 years behind the
profession."
When will the dismal science catch up with reality? Judging
by my
inquiries, probably not anytime soon—and maybe not before its adepts
have vaporized what little is left of American economic prowess.
In
the reality-based community, the attitude towards the economics
profession
could hardly be more sullen. Thom Hartmann, a talk-show host
and author who
ranks as one of the American media's most impassioned
critics of globalism,
points out that, in marked contrast to economic
theoreticians, ordinary
Americans have long sensed there is something
wrong with trade policy. "To
the extent there is a trend, it is at the
grassroots," he says. "People have
seen the factories go, and now many
of the jobs that cannot be exported are
being filled by illegals.
Ordinary Americans don't understand the
theoretical issues but they are
gravitating to a very simplistic nationalism
reminiscent of Europe in
the 1930s."
Many even of America's thinking
classes are no longer willing to drink
the Kool-Aid. As the most recent
presidential administrations have
staggered from one economic debacle to
another, economists have found
themselves pilloried not only for failing to
offer timely warnings of
the dangers ahead but, in far too many cases, for
the erstwhile rapture
with which they endorsed the policies that resulted in
the Wall Street
train wreck. The result, as the Washington-based commentator
James
Fallows has pointed out, is that there is increasing doubt these days
about almost every aspect of established economic wisdom. Fallows, an
author on East Asian trade who learned his economics as a Rhodes scholar
at Oxford, adds: "I don't think that anything as coherent as a new view,
or systematic critique, has emerged. It's more an inchoate sense that
the established ‘laws' and principles are increasingly mismatched to the
observed realities."
Although the number of economists prepared to
question conventional
trade theory openly has steadily risen in recent
years, they remain a
small minority—and a marginalized one. Even as evidence
mounts that the
profession is presiding over one of the most remarkable
fiascos in
intellectual history, many factors discourage waverers from
breaking ranks.
Most obviously, the textbook industry's self-censorship
makes it
difficult for even skeptical teachers to provide a balanced,
nuanced
account. Young teachers aspiring to tenure are well advised to keep
their more heterodox opinions to themselves.
"Change does not come
easily in academic life," says Prasch. "For the
most part we will have to
await the gravedigger's shovel. Guys in their
fifties rarely admit that what
they have been teaching all their lives
is balderdash."
Darker forces
may also be at work. Paul Craig Roberts, a principal
architect of
Reaganomics who in recent years has become one of the
right's most
penetrating critics of globalism, has suggested that many
globalist-leaning
economists are "bought and paid for." What is clear is
that academics who
aspire to moonlight as corporate consultants have
little choice but to
endorse orthodox views on things like offshoring.
And, of course, no analyst
flourishes in Wall Street's gravitational
field without toeing the
line.
Nonetheless, turmoil is evident just below the surface. The
metaphor of
a volcano about to blow is overworked but it well describes the
intellectual pressures that have been building for years.
The
earliest rumblings came from economists on the left, some of whom
began
focusing on trade's impact on jobs as far back as the 1970s. Most
such
skeptics—they included Jeff Madrick, Jeff Faux, Barry Bluestone,
Bennett
Harrison, and Robert Reich, and they were soon joined by younger
colleagues
such as Dean Baker, Laura Tyson, and Ira Magaziner—were
advocates of
industrial policy. That stance almost by definition implied
a wary view of
free trade. It also made them easy to marginalize. Such
is the esteem with
which free trade theory is viewed by almost the
entire economics profession,
in the early days proponents of industrial
policy shrank from an
all-guns-blazing assault on the consensus.
As the years have gone by,
however, they have not only become more
emboldened but have been joined by
some on the right. Hence the sight
today of President Reagan's assistant
Treasury secretary Paul Craig
Roberts making common cause with liberal peers
such as James K.
Galbraith, Herman Daly, and Ronald Baiman, not to mention
journalist
Alexander Cockburn. (It should be noted, however, that Roberts
draws a
sharp distinction between traditional free trade and the recent
phenomenon of offshoring. Roberts argues that offshoring is not true
free trade as understood by classical economists. So while he opposes
offshoring, he upholds the classical version of free trade, which
assumed among other things that all a nation's capital would be invested
at home.)
Among the earliest challengers, two names particularly
stand out—Robert
Kuttner and John M. Culbertson. They both threw down the
gauntlet in
1984. Kuttner came from the industrial-policy school and was
then just
starting to make a name for himself as an economic
journalist.
Culbertson was a more startling case. Having worked as a
young economist
for the Federal Reserve System, he later taught at the
University of
Wisconsin-Madison. Previously known for rather staid work on
monetary
policy, he crossed a professional Rubicon with the publication of
International Trade and the Future of the West. The profession's
response can be aptly summed up in the Japanese term mokusatsu—"killing
with silence." A search of LexisNexis reveals just two reviews, in
National Journal and Foreign Affairs, and in the latter case his
apostasy was dismissed in just five sentences.
Indeed, so out of step
was he with all respectable opinion that he had
to resort to publishing the
book himself—a gambit that all but
guaranteed his slightly
amateurish-looking effort would be consigned
unopened to literary editors'
garbage cans. Such editors are of course
busy people and in reflexively
ignoring self-published authors their
instinct is almost always right. But
Culbertson has proved a spectacular
exception. With each passing year his
challenge to the consensus is
looking more inspired. He predicted that
low-wage foreign competition
would precipitate the collapse of the American
middle class—the
so-called race to the bottom that has recently been the
subject of an
eponymous book by Alan Tonelson.
In a field known for
obscure language and ample resort to subordinate
clauses, Culbertson's
writing style left nothing to the imagination.
Here is a sample: "In
economic affairs, the decades ahead must be a time
of change and challenge,
indeed a time of ‘sink or swim.'… Unless
economic change is shifted to a new
pattern, brought under intelligent
control, the years ahead could bring
cumulative deterioration and
demoralization to the United States, the West,
and to much of the world."
He added: "Many economists wear blinders that
will induce them to
continue their crusade against ‘protectionism' all the
way to the
sinking of the West. … Will the United States and the West … come
to
interpret international trade realistically, and respond intelligently
to the situation that actually exists? This question is decisive for the
future of the West."
Like Culbertson, Kuttner issued his challenge
via a book. In The
Economic Illusion, he presented an analysis that went far
further than
that of other liberal economic commentators in targeting the
core of the
free-trade consensus. That core is, of course, the venerable
theory of
comparative advantage formulated by the British banker David
Ricardo as
far back as 1817.
Kuttner argued that the world had
changed since Ricardo. While Ricardian
theory assumed a static world in
which the structure of trade reflected
mainly each nation's natural
endowments—Ricardo famously cited Britain's
advantage in making woolen cloth
versus Portugal's in wine—Kuttner
pointed out that, in modern manufacturing,
nations can judiciously rig
their markets to conjure up productivity
advantages where none existed
before. This is particularly likely—and is
particularly consequential—in
high-tech goods. With the help of an elaborate
array of industrial
policies, Japan, for instance, has come from nowhere in
the 1950s to
achieve dominance almost right across the board in advanced
manufacturing, particularly in capital goods, which though invisible to
consumers are essential for finished-goods producers such as those in
China and other low-wage nations.
Kuttner also pointed out that
Ricardo's theory depends on other hidden
assumptions that have become
increasingly unrealistic over the years.
The theory works as advertised only
if there is no significant
unemployment or unused production capacity, for
instance. It is a long
time since those conditions existed in
America.
By the latter half of the 1980s, support for trade dogma began
cracking
even among the American right. One of the first prominent
conservatives
to break with the consensus was Patrick Buchanan. Another
notably early
challenge came in 1986 from Pat Choate, an economist who
advised TRW,
then a major player in several high-tech industries. Choate,
who had
already identified himself as an advocate of industrial policy as
far
back as 1980, focused on the practical politics of trade, particularly
East Asian mercantilism, which in its Japanese manifestation was already
a red-hot issue.
Japan's often preposterous excuses for shutting out
American goods had
long become notorious. Most memorably, in comments that
were clearly
intended to drive a wedge between Republicans and Democrats,
Tokyo
blamed trade imbalances sometimes on incompetent American managers,
who
allegedly did not try hard enough to understand the Japanese market, and
sometimes on American workers, who allegedly were lazy or
uneducated.
Although the instinct in Washington, particularly among
mainstream
economists and other proponents of Ricardian doctrine, was to
challenge
every jot and tittle of Japanese rhetoric, Choate argued that the
United
States should simply accept that Japan did not believe in free trade
and
never would. Further efforts to remake Japanese society along American
lines would be a fool's errand and would only foster resentment and
circumvention in Japan. Meanwhile the attempt would delay disastrously
any effective remedy for American manufacturers, many of whom were
already then on their last legs.
Thus, in a recommendation that
scandalized orthodox American economists,
Choate, who went on to achieve
prominence as Ross Perot's running mate
in the 1996 presidential election,
became one of the first proponents of
"managed trade": Washington should, he
said, simply set targets for
Japan's imports and ask Tokyo to use its
various industrial-policy
levers to meet them.
Of all the challenges
to the consensus, none has created more
intellectual shockwaves than the
Gomory-Baumol analysis. Although when
it was first unveiled in 2000 it
received far less publicity than Paul
Samuelson's similar later contribution
would, within the economics
profession many recognized it as having holed
the orthodoxy below the
waterline. Indeed, in the view of Paul Craig
Roberts, Gomory-Baumol is
probably the most important development in trade
economics since
Ricardo's own theory.
The authors' credentials are
hard to shrug off. Gomory is a world-class
mathematician who in a former
life as director of research for IBM saw
first-hand how sharply global
competition in high-tech industries
diverges from traditional theory. Baumol
is a New York University
economics professor who served as president of the
American Economics
Association in the 1980s.
The Gomory-Baumol
analysis goes further than any other in examining the
assumptions
underpinning free-trade orthodoxy. In focusing on the role
of assumptions,
Gomory draws an analogy with how objects in the physical
world behave under
the influence of gravity. As he points out, in
predicting the trajectory of
falling objects, sometimes you have to take
the effect of air into
account—in addition to the force of gravity—and
sometimes you don't. If you
insist on ignoring air all the time you will
end up predicting that
airplanes won't fly—that they will just fall to
the ground.
Similarly
with economic models, your assumptions have to be chosen with
care. "The
Ricardo model describes pure market forces acting in a world
where
production capabilities don't change," Gomory points out. "But
today
production capabilities do change. China is a great example."
Using the
Ricardo model as a starting point, Gomory and Baumol
considered not just one
set of productivities but all possible
productivities in different
circumstances and at different times. Using
the Ricardo model that way they
could investigate, for example, how your
trading partner's economic
development affects you as his productivities
change. They got a very
non-obvious answer: your trading partner's
economic development is at first
good for you, and then, as your trading
partner becomes more and more
developed, bad for you.
And of course, as Gomory points out, market
forces are not the only
forces at work. Governments help their industries in
many ways, from tax
breaks to making technology transfer a prerequisite for
market entry.
These non-market forces are strong incentives affecting what
companies do.
"The market forces are still there," says Gomory "and we
have to take
account of them through models such as the Ricardo one, but if
we don't
also take seriously the non-market forces, we may reach conclusions
that
may be as wrong as predicting that airplanes can't
fly."
Airplanes do fly, of course. And mercantilism can work. Certainly
the
East Asian variety does.
As someone who has lived in Tokyo since
1985, I have long enjoyed a
special vantage point from which to watch the
trade debate. I am struck
by how parochial are most Anglophone discussions
and how little they
take account of easily documented reality in other parts
of the planet.
Certainly the world looks very different from Tokyo, not
least because
East Asian leaders are convinced that, in its ever more
heedless
commitment to laissez faire, the United States is digging its own
grave.
But of course, East Asians are discreet people and, short of being
waterboarded, they are unlikely to ever offer a frank opinion on an
American mindset that happens to have done so much to transfer
industrial leadership to East Asia.
It has long been obvious to
Tokyo-based observers that, where trade is
concerned, the world is divided
into two economic camps—on the one hand,
nations that generally run a trade
surplus and on the other those that
run chronic deficits. The United States,
of course, now ranks as the
all-time champion in the latter camp, but it
shares its heedlessness
with most of the English-speaking world, including
the United Kingdom,
Ireland, Australia, New Zealand, India, and
Pakistan.
By contrast, nations that generally run surpluses include not
only
virtually all of the East Asians, but Germany, Sweden, Austria,
Switzerland, the Netherlands, and other rich European
nations.
Largely overlooked in the Anglophone media, the two camps are
polar
opposites in several policy matters, most obviously their approach to
exchange rates. Anglophone nations have generally taken pride in
strong—i.e., overvalued—currencies and have rushed to the barricades
when threatened with depreciation. (This mindset was epitomized most
absurdly by the "defend the pound" antics of a sickly post-imperial
Britain in the 1960s and 1970s.) In contrast, the surplus nations have
rejoiced in low exchange rates.
To be sure, the United States
recently has undergone a partial change of
heart with respect to the Chinese
yuan. But U.S. policymakers still show
little interest in securing
competitive exchange rates for their
exporters against the Germans, the
Japanese, and the Koreans.
The dichotomy in mindset between surplus and
deficit nations raises many
questions. Why, for instance, do Anglophone
economists win so many Nobel
Prizes and their peers in such robust surplus
nations as Japan, China,
Korea, and Germany so few? And, conversely, why are
Japanese, Chinese,
Korean, and German exporters so much more effective than
their American
and British counterparts in world markets? The answers will
wait for
another time, but it is a fair bet that there are more things in
heaven
and earth than are dreamt of in American economics
textbooks.
Eamonn Fingleton is the author of In the Jaws of the Dragon:
America's
Fate in the Coming Era of Chinese Dominance.
(6) Obituary:
John M. Culbertson, economist who defended Protectionism
http://www.sfgate.com/news/article/John-M-Culbertson-2839502.php
John
M. Culbertson
December 17, 2001 | By New York Times
John M.
Culbertson, an economist known for mounting an articulate
defense of
protectionist economic policy long after the tenets of free
trade were de
rigueur among his colleagues, died Dec. 9 in Madison, Wis.
He was
80.
He had been suffering from Parkinson's disease, according to his
wife,
Frances.
Mr. Culbertson began his career as a specialist in
monetary issues for
the Federal Reserve System in Washington in the 1950s.
He shifted his
focus to trade relatively late in his career, in the 1970s,
nearly two
decades after he became a tenured professor at the University of
Wisconsin.
He was born in 1921 in Detroit and grew up on a farm in Walled
Lake,
Mich. His undergraduate education at the University of Michigan was
interrupted by World War II, when he served in the U.S. Army Air Corps
as an instructor of pilots and a pilot of B-26 Marauders in
Europe.
Mr. Culbertson became well known when support for protectionism
grew in
the 1980s as concern grew about companies' decisions to shift
manufacturing and jobs from the United States to cheaper countries and
about swelling imports from other nations, especially Japan.
He was a
passionate advocate of protectionism, favoring tariffs to limit
imports and
other barriers designed to shield domestic industries from
the threat of
foreign competition. Mr. Culbertson's ideas were well
received by unions,
but he had many detractors in university faculties
and research
groups.
"The future of the United States depends on whether we can escape
from
the childish dream world in which 'free trade' is The Good Fairy, and
'protectionism' is The Wicked Witch of the West," Mr. Culbertson wrote
in an essay in 1986.
Unable to find publishers for his books and
concerned that the
University of Wisconsin Press would not enthusiastically
promote his
work, he formed his own publishing concern, 21st Century Press.
He
designed the typeface for the press on a personal computer and promoted
books with flyers sent to prospective readers.
Using that strategy,
Mr. Culbertson published several books in the
1980s, including "Competition,
Constructive and Destructive" and "The
Dangers of 'Free Trade.'
(7)
U.S. 'Free Trade' with Mexico, by John Culbertson
http://www.thesocialcontract.com/artman2/publish/tsc1504/article_1328_printer.shtml
U.S.
'Free Trade' with Mexico
By John Culbertson
Published in The
Social Contract
Volume 15, Number 4 (Summer 2005)
Issue theme:
"Special anniversary issue: highlights from our first
fifteen
years"
http://www.thesocialcontract.com/artman2/publish/tsc1504/article_1328.shtml
The
topic of 'free trade' is as current as this morning's paper which is
why
this article by John Culbertson is as timely today as it was when
written in
1991. Culbertson has long been a doubting Thomas' on the
subject of free
trade' to the irritation of the economic fraternity
where such challenges
are definitely not politically correct.
Depending on the world-view and
vocabulary used to depict it, U.S. free
trade with Mexico can seem anything
from an obviously progressive step
to an action ruinous to the United States
and damaging to human
prospects. The favorable interpretation now prevailing
in both the
political right and left in the United States proves, on
consideration,
to reflect a misleading conceptualization of the subject
arising from a
fashionable utopian ideology.
Seeking the truth on
this subject thus requires first its
depropagandization. The valid name for
what is called "free trade" is
"foreign trade not subject to regulation by
the nation's government,"
that is, mandatory deregulation of the nation's
foreign trade - like
deregulation of its savings associations, banks,
airlines. The valid
name for what is called "barriers to trade" is
"regulation of trade."
The misleading labels present an image of regulation
of foreign trade as
unnatural and inherently destructive, a crime against
the ways of the
world. In truth, foreign trade has always been regulated by
governments.
The human world always has been made up of many independent,
or "free,"
tribes, kingdoms, empires, or nations. Preserving this structure
of
human life requires the regulation of foreign trade. Unregulated foreign
trade undercuts the independence of nations, prevents their developing
along different paths. In the absence of effective supranational
government, the deregulation of foreign trade leaves mankind adrift, its
diverse and discordant societies merged into impotence, dropped together
into a single pot, with no government at any level that is capable of
preserving a civilized level of life or preventing the destruction of
the earthly habitat. Far from being obviously correct, unregulated
foreign trade is revolutionary; fashionably but irresponsibly
revolutionary.
The free-trade fable exercises its mind-ruling power by
exploiting the
human weakness for making issues a struggle between Good and
Evil. It
provides a stereotype of regulation of foreign trade as
"protectionism,"
depicted as "import restrictions that damage the nation and
the world
but are imposed through the power of evil 'special interests'."
The evil
"protectionists" are portrayed as acting out of anti-social
selfishness
or of racism, an urge to bash some nation, or a show of
indifference to
foreign poverty. In the Good-versus-Evil conceptualization
of foreign
trade, protectionism/the Evil, commonly is depicted as the only
option
other than free trade/the Good. President Reagan's consistent
characterization of his trade policy for the United States as one of
"fighting protectionism" illustrates the pattern.
Is it true that the
only options on foreign-trade policy are free trade
or protectionism? The
trade policy, through which Japan took over
valuable U.S. markets,
industries, and jobs through one-sided foreign
trade, ran huge trade
surpluses with the U.S. and become large owners of
U.S. properties is this
free trade or is it protectionism? Of course,
the answer is neither neither
the answer for Japan nor for most other
nations. In reality, there are many
kinds of trade policy available.
Posing the choice as "free trade or
protectionism" illustrates a basic
technique in the manipulative use of
language, the misstated either-or,
as in Hitler's proffered choice Nazism or
Jewish communism; Stalinism's
idealized socialism or Satanic capitalism. The
stereotype of
protectionism functions as a contrived Evil to be paired with
free trade
as the Good. Given the effectiveness with which such
propagandistic use
of language has been analyzed by Hayakawa and others, it
is surprising
that self-respecting Americans across the political spectrum,
both
Ronald Reagan and the editorial writers of The New York Times, rely on
it to support the deregulation of foreign trade with no consideration of
the actual effects of alternative trade policies. Economists commonly
use the same conceptualization, contrasting the negatively stereotyped
protectionism with misleading examples in which unregulated foreign
trade automatically brings the best of all possible worlds examples that
do not correspond to evidence and experience.
Thus, to consider
alternative trade policies in terms of their effects
requires escaping from
the whole system of deceptive stereotypes that
dominates U.S. discussion of
the subject. A realistic consideration of
the effects of alternative systems
of foreign trade can well begin with
the observation of the great liberal
economist, J. M. Keynes ("National
Self-Sufficiency," Yale Review, 1933)
that the system of foreign trade
must be chosen to fit the political,
economic, social, and
international-relations realities of the times.
Keynes, deploring his
own zealous earlier support of the free-trade
doctrine, pointed out that
it made no sense to attempt to bring about
laissez-faire foreign trade
in the political and economic world of the 20th
century whether or not
it would have been reasonable in an earlier
era.
Keynes recognized the all-important point that unregulated foreign
trade
implied "economic entanglement among nations." Unregulated foreign
trade
subordinates the goals, standards, powers of the nation to the
interests
of private parties in all nations. Deregulating its foreign trade
costs
a nation its freedom of action, its effective independence, its
ability
to chart its own course and to learn its own lessons from its
successes
and its failures.
The nineteenth-century vision of
world-wide deregulation of foreign
trade in the context of universal
economic laissez-faire thus had no
applicability to the political and
economic world that arose from the
First World War, in which nations
explicitly adopted different theories,
ideologies, and policy goals. The
political and economic situation of
the 20th century required policies that
could bring about constructive,
mutually beneficial patterns of foreign
trade among independent nations
operating under different political and
economic agendas and goals. "We
do not wish, therefore, to be at the mercy
of world forces working out
... some uniform equilibrium according to the
ideal principles, if they
can be called such, of laissez-faire capitalism.
We wish ... to be our
own masters and to be as free as we can make ourselves
from the
interferences of the outside world," wrote
Keynes.
{quote}
I sympathize, therefore, with those who would
minimize, rather than with
those who would maximize, economic entanglement
among nations. Ideas,
knowledge, science, hospitality, travel these are the
things which
should of their nature be international. But let goods be
homespun
whenever it is reasonably and conveniently possible, and, above
all, let
finance be primarily national. For these strong reasons, therefore,
I am
inclined to the belief that ... a greater measure of national
self-sufficiency and economic isolation among countries than existed in
1914 may serve the cause of peace rather than
otherwise.
{endquote}
Keynes noted that any loss of production
efficiency from maintaining a
nation's economic independence was in many
cases small or trivial and
that the existence and amount of any such
"inefficiency" depends on
circumstances and cannot be inferred from
ideologically-biased
"principles" "Experience accumulates to prove that most
modern processes
of mass production can be performed in most countries and
climates with
almost equal efficiency."
In Keynes' valid conception
of "efficiency," for example, shifting the
production of telephones for the
U.S. market from a factory in Louisiana
to an identical factory in Thailand
does not increase efficiency; it
reduces efficiency but is profitable
because it replaces high-income
labor with low-income labor. Shifting world
manufacturing production
from high-wage to low-wage nations does not
increase efficiency and
world output. An increase in the volume of world
trade of this type is
not progress; it may be ruinous.
Foreign trade
of genuine efficiency would provide the means of
permanently benefitting
both nations rather than temporarily benefitting
one nation at the expense
of the other. In real-world conditions, such
efficiency-based and mutually
beneficial patterns of foreign trade are
ordinarily attainable only on the
basis of a set of constructive trade
policies. That the basic distinction
between efficiency-based,
beneficial trade and level-the-nations-downward
trade has been lost in
recent discussion, even by most economists, perhaps
must be explained by
the dominance of propaganda in the discussion of
foreign trade, which
has hidden even the most basic causal
relations.
Keynes thus favored a system of regulated foreign trade that
would work
constructively in a world of free and independent non-globalized
nations. That is, he favored a system of constructively regulated
foreign trade, which is not so-called "free trade" and is not so-called
"protectionism." But historical accidents put the path of opinion and
events since the 1930s under the domination of a massive U.S. attempt to
implement a peculiar version of world-wide "free trade."
The
intellectual and political father of this movement was Cordell Hull,
the
U.S. Secretary of State from 1933 to 1944. The rationale of Hull's
pursuit
of deregulation of foreign trade differed from the now-dominant
one. Having
conceived as early as 1916 that "unhampered trade
dove-tailed with peace;
high tariffs, trade barriers, and unfair
economic competition with war,"
Hull and his U.S. State Department
developed the concepts and the program
that still underlie the U.S.
campaign for the deregulation of foreign trade
to attack not an alleged
economic inefficiency of "protectionism" but
asserted war-causing
effects of international economic rivalries and "trade
wars."
Hull was able to gain acquiescence in his version of foreign-trade
deregulation during the temporary U.S. dominance of the world at the end
of the Second World War. Keynes never supported Hull's approach,
referring to "the lunatic proposals of Mr. Hull." Had Keynes' view
governed the postwar arrangements for foreign trade, international
economic and political developments would have taken a quite different
course. It was not the inexorable march of progress but a curious set of
circumstances that brought the world-trade situation to its present
crisis.
Patterns of trade that benefit both of the nations involved do
not arise
naturally from the profit-seeking dealings of private parties of
all
nations. Mutually beneficial foreign trade requires a constructive
framework of national trade policy that (1) prevents out-of-balance or
one-way trade that shifts industries, jobs, and economic ownership from
a trade-deficit to a trade-surplus nation, (2) prevents the shifting of
the industries with bright futures to one nation thus leaving to the
other nation only the declining and low-pay industries, (3) prevents
nations from being damaged by instability imposed by the trade, such as
the "dumping" of goods in a foreign market below production cost to
weaken its industry and take over its market, (4) prevents the pattern
of trade from unduly undermining the independence and defense
capabilities of the nation, and (5) avoids the one-sidedness of trade
benefit that arises when the trade on one side is arranged on behalf of
the nation by its government and on the other side is handled by firms
that are competing against one another in pursuit of private
profit.
The foreign-trade arrangements arising from the Hull approach
were not
aimed at these goals. They proved to thwart their achievement.
Hull's
effort to reduce average tariff levels and trade "discrimination" (in
a
peculiar sense) through the "most-favored-nation" policy prevented the
development of managed, mutually beneficial patterns of trade between
nations in different circumstances. In this approach, if the United
States, say, made a certain trade concession to Mexico in order to work
out a balanced and mutually beneficial pattern of trade with Mexico, the
United States (to avoid "discrimination") would have to offer the same
concession to Japan and other countries that already had large trade
surpluses with the U.S.
One epoch-making "side effect" of the
Hull-structured trade policy was
to cause the United States to acquiesce
year after year after year in a
ruinous pattern of one-sided,
one-way-benefit foreign trade that
permitted its all-important home market
for the rewarding-to-the-nation
industries of the times to be taken over by
other nations, largely on
the basis of their low-wages, minimal regulations
and social standards,
and government management of their foreign trade. The
economic decline
of the United States would not have occurred as it did
under a
foreign-trade system that paid attention to the effects of the
patterns
of trade and provided means for nations to arrange mutually
beneficial
patterns of trade.
The Free-Trade/Good -
Protectionism/Evil view of foreign trade thus has
caused enormous mischief.
It has the world headed for worsening
problems. Low-wage and
low-labor-standards nations around the world
expect to advance themselves by
taking over rising shares of the U.S.
market, which is shrinking as a result
of the trade-caused economic
decline of the United States and its standard
of living. The
foreign-trade system is headed for crisis a crisis that
should have been
easy to predict, but will be far from easy to
cure.
A factor curiously neglected in recent trade-policy discussion is
the
radical effect on the process of rise and decline of human societies
that would be caused by the entanglement, amalgamation, or merger of
nations resulting from the deregulation of foreign trade. It now is
widely understood that the basis of constructive organic,
organizational, and societal evolution is diversity, variety, copious
experimentation, multiple trials in the trial and error of the
evolutionary process. Advancement perhaps even survival requires enough
variety of experiments to generate some successes. Of the human
societies of the present era, many have recently conceded failure and
others seem to be headed for it. But human civilization has a future so
long as there are some successes some societies that meet the short-run
and long-run requirements of their environments, providing patterns that
can be copied or adapted by the failing societies.
Biologists argue
that the survival of even an obscure species of owl may
be important for
mankind because it affects the earth's biological
diversity. How much more
important it must be that there exist a large
and diverse set of human
societies, exploring different developmental
paths, demon-strating "what
happens if...," providing patterns of
success that can be used to repair
failures and potential
extinguishments of other societies. But because trade
policy is
discussed within misleading verbal stereotypes, these profound
implications are not recognized to exist.
It is clear as, again,
Keynes took for granted that nations that give up
their power to regulate
their foreign trade, in general or with
particular nations, give up their
independence of action and control of
their future course of development.
The actual implementation of "free
trade" would replace many, diverse,
nation-guided societal experiments
with a single global experiment that
presumably would be guided by no
effective government.
One critically
important consideration is that under a "global economy,"
"one world," or
the rule of "free trade," the effects of
overpopulation-caused poverty and
joblessness would fall not on the
society that causes the problem but on all
nations, as competition
shifts capital and production to the nation with the
lowest labor-cost.
In a world of independent societies, the failure of any
one does not
drag down the others. The failures can turn themselves around
by copying
the successes. In a world of one "global economy," failures
anywhere
drag all downward. The expected result is universal failure and
degradation. On a planet critically threatened by human overpopulation,
habitat destruction, and governments too weak or delusion-based to
preserve the habitat and standard of living, the prospects of mankind as
one single, globalized experiment are dismal.
Most recent discussion
depicts the "the global economy" or "one world"
not as bringing
all-eggs-in-one-basket human failure, but as fighting
"nationalism" which is
stereotyped as based on bigotry, racism, hatred,
selfishness, or
anti-progressiveness. Once again, the purported choice
'aggressive,
bigotry-based nationalism,' (the Evil) or 'global economy,'
(the Good) -
misstates the options that are available. Neither
"aggressive nationalism"
nor "the global economy" is a course that
merits serious consideration.
Success can be gained only by escaping
from such misleading stereotypes
(which seem rooted in their own
bigotries) and realistically defining the
available policy options and
their expected outcomes.
The economic
merger of, or free trade between, two nations makes these
nations subject to
the downward-levelling effect of unregulated foreign
trade, diminishes
national independence and diversity, and undercuts the
capabilities of both
national governments while providing no new forms
of government to take
their place. In such cases, the first-stage
outcome depends on the
compatibility of the two societies that enter
into the economic-political
merger or partnership. The more alike they
are the less there is to be lost
in world societal diversity and in
detrimental effect on one or both
nations. Thus, economic merger of the
U.S. and Canada is much less
threatening than that of the U.S. and
Mexico, or the U.S. and China, or
India.
The U.S. and Mexico differ widely in political tradition,
ideology,
government structure and performance, severity of overpopulation
and
excessive population-growth, unemployment, low-wage production,
worker-protection standards, child labor laws, environmental protection
attitudes and policies, cultures, values, viewpoints and language. Free
trade and economic, political, cultural, social merger between two
countries as different and disharmonious as these cannot be justified on
the basis of an experience-based, cause-and-effect analysis of the
likely effects. The conceivable gain is, at best, trivial in relation to
the conceivable loss, which is almost beyond imagining. Any real
potential gain from trade between the nations could be tapped through
managed and mutually beneficial trade that preserved the independence of
the two nations and threatened no ruinous outcome.
The damage done by
a trade-deregulation merger of two nations need not
fall on them equally.
Nations with bright prospects have more to lose
than those with dismal
prospects. Mexican workers might seem certain, at
least temporarily, to gain
(at the expense of American workers, and of a
rising role of American
capital in Mexico) from the shift of production,
jobs, industries, capital
from the U.S. to Mexico because of
cost-savings from lower wages and less
stringent regulation of child
labor, worker protection, and working
conditions. But when the
discordant nations sat down to, as it is put,
'harmonize' their laws and
policies in a way that is satisfactory to their
diverse constituencies
and found how little agreement and how much conflict
exists, it would
become clear that while each nation alone had a chance of
finding a path
to success, in their joint harness they could not agree on
any path that
would meet the requirements of the times and achieve
success.
As the United States, despite its recent lack of realism and its
self-destructive policies, still must be counted among the nations that
might generate patterns of success that merit copying by other nations,
it would diminish the hopes of mankind for the U.S. to enter blindly
into nation-mergers that would remove it from the potential contributors
of patterns of societal economic success. From the viewpoint of
Americans (except perhaps of some capitalists) U.S. merger with Mexico
or with almost any other nation would be insane.
Thus, the pursuit of
"free trade," "a global economy," and U.S. "free
trade" with Mexico seem (1)
a grand and inspiring program for progress
when viewed within the
stereotypes now dominating U.S. discussion but as
(2) a uniquely destructive
human folly when viewed within the framework
of cause-and-effect
analysis.
Where are the voices of those who understand the second view?
Is the
Congress to commit the nation's future without even an awareness that
this view exists?
Extricating nations from the collapse of an
ideology-based,
deeply-embedded economic structure that proves a failure is
being shown
by the cases of collapsing Marxist communism to be very
difficult and of
uncertain outcome even when models of success are available
to be
copied. If the United States, beguiled by its misleading stereotypes
of
utopian individualism and anti-nationalism, blind to the effects that
actually will follow (and have followed) from its actions, commits
itself, and pushes other nations, to an ungovernable,
all-the-human-eggs-in-one-basket structuring of mankind in a rapidly
deteriorating and increasingly overpopulated earthly habitat, the
prospects of recovering from the collapse of this structure will not be
favorable.
About the author
John M. Culbertson, Ph.D., is
emeritus professor of economics at the
University of
Wisconsin-Madison.
His most recent book on the topic of free trade is The
Trade Threat and
US Trade Policy. In this article he encourages us to use,
and think in,
different terms when discussing globalization and foreign
trade.
Copyright 2007 The Social Contract Press, 445 E Mitchell Street,
Petoskey, MI 49770; ISSN 1055-145X
(Article copyrights extend to the
first date the article was published
in The Social Contract)
No comments:
Post a Comment
Note: Only a member of this blog may post a comment.