Michael Hudson on the history of Interest-Bearing Debt, and of Debt
Amnesty
Newsletter published on April 6, 2019
The Delphic Oracle Was Their Davos: A
Four-Part Interview With Michael
Hudson About His Forthcoming Book The Collapse of Antiquity (Part
1)
Posted on April 2, 2019 by Yves
Smith
Yves here. Classicist John Siman and Michael Hudson got to know each other
at NC meetup last year, which led to the series of conversations that is
codified in this series. Here, Hudson describes in antiquity, how oligarchs in
Greece and Rome ended the practice of debt jubilees and became
rentiers.
By John Siman
Note: Michael Hudson published … and forgive
them their debts: Lending, Foreclosure, and Redemption From Bronze Age Finance
to the Jubilee Year in November of last year. It is the first volume in what
will be a trilogy on the long history of the tyranny of debt. I have interviewed
him extensively as he writes the second volume, The Collapse of
Antiquity.
John
Siman: Michael, inthe first volume of your history
of debt — "
… and forgive them their debts, dealing with
the Bronze Age Near East, Judaism and early Christianity — you showed how over
thousands of years, going back to the invention of interest-bearing loans in
Mesopotamia in the third millennium BC, many kings from a variety of Mesopotamian
civilizations proclaimed Clean Slate debt cancellations on a more or less
regular basis. And you showed that these royal proclamations of debt amnesty
rescued the lower classes from debt
bondage, maintaining a workable economic balance over many centuries.
Because these kings were so powerful — and, let’s say, enlightened — they were
able to prevent the social and economic polarization that is inevitable when
there is no check on an oligarchic creditor class extracting exponentially
increasing interest from debtors.
But now, as you write the second volume,
your theme gets turned upside down. You are showing how the Greeks and the Romans learned about
interest-bearing debt from their contacts with Middle Eastern civilizations, but
tragically failed to institute
programs of Clean Slate debt
amnesty. Their failure has been a kind of albatross around the neck of
Western economies ever since.
So I’d like to start this conversation in
the late 500s BC, because we can see at that time the beginnings of both the
Athenian democracy and the Roman Republic, plus of two more important
civilizations. First was the Athens of Cleisthenes, who had led the overthrow
the "tyrant" Hippias and became the father of Athenian democracy. Second, there
was the Roman Republic of Lucius Junius Brutus, who overthrew the last of Rome’s
legendary kings, the "tyrant" Tarquinius Superbus.Third was the Persian
civilization of Cyrus the Great. He was a "divine king," in many ways in the
ancient tradition of Hammurabi. Fourth were the post-exilic Jews of Ezra and
Nehemiah, who returned to Jerusalem, rebuilt the Temple and redacted the Bible.
They were the inventors of the Jubilee years of Clean Slate debt forgiveness,
even though they depicted the teaching as coming from Moses.
So, beginning with the late 500s BC, to what
extent was the notion of Clean Slate debt amnesty remembered, and to what extent
was it rejected?
Michael Hudson: Every kind of reform,
from Mesopotamia to Greece, was put forth as if it simply restored the way
things were in the beginning. There was
no concept of linear progress in Antiquity. They thought that there was only
one way to do things, so any reform must be the way the world was meant to be in
the very beginning. All reformers would say that in the beginning everybody must have been
equal. Their reform was aimed at restoring this state of affairs.
That’s why, when Plutarch and even the
Spartan kings in the third century BC
talked about canceling debts and promoting equality, they said that they
were simply restoring the original
system that Lycurgus had created. But there was no sign that Lycurgus had
really done these things. It was made up. Lycurgus was a legendary figure. So was
Moses in the Jewish tradition. When the Bible was redacted and put together
after the return from Babylon, they put debt cancellation and land
redistribution —the Jubilee Year — right in the center of Mosaic Law. So it
seemed that this was not an innovation, but what Moses said in the beginning.
They created a Moses figure much like the Greeks created a Lycurgus figure. They
said that this is how things were meant to be. This is how it was in the
beginning — and it just happened to be their own program.
This was a projection backwards: a
retrojection. Felix Jacoby wrote that Athenian history was that way, basically
party pamphleteering projecting their ideal program back to Solon or to whomever
one might choose as a good guy to model. Writers would then say that this
original good guy supported the program that they were proposing in their epoch.
This was the ancient analogy to
"Constitutional Originalism" in the United States as a frame for right-wing
policies.
JS: So, ever since the 500s BC, the
surefire way to critique the status quo has been to say you are trying to go
back to the Garden of Eden or to some other pristine Saturnian Golden
Age.
MH: Yes, you want to say that the unfair
world around you isn’t what was meant, so this couldn’t have been the original
plan, because the past had to be a successful takeoff. So the program that
reformers always turned out to be what the Founding Fathers meant.
JS: That’s veryinspirational!
MH: The key is to appear as a
conservative, not a radical. You accuse the existing status quo as being the
beneficiaries of the radicals who have distorted the original Fair Plan that
you’re trying to restore.
JS: So in the 500s BC we have Cyrus — and
his inscription on the Cyrus Cylinder — boasting that he freed the Babylonians
from their tax debt and bonds, and we have the post-exilic Jews proclaiming
d’ror [????????] in Leviticus 25, proclaiming "liberty throughout the land." We
also have the reforms of Cleisthenes in Athens, isonomia [?sonom?a, literally,
equality under the law], a genuine attempt at democracy. But let’s start with
Rome. What do you want to say about the nova libertas, the "new liberty"
proclaimed in Rome after the last king was expelled and the Republic was
founded? Didn’t Brutus and his wellborn friends boast that they were the
institutors of true liberty?
MH: Liberty for them was the liberty to
destroy that of the population at large. Instead of cancelling debts and
restoring land tenure to the population, the oligarchy created the Senate that
protected the right of creditors to enslave labor and seize public as well as private lands
(just as had occurred in Athens before Solon). Instead of restoring a status
quo ante of free cultivators — free of debt and tax obligations, as Sumerian
amargi and Babylonian misharumand andurarum meant — the Roman oligarchy accused anyone of supporting
debtor rights and opposing its land grabs of "seeking kingship." Such men were murdered, century after
century.
Rome was turned into an oligarchy, an autocracy of the
senatorial families. Their "liberty" was an early example of Orwellian
Doublethink. It was to destroy everybody else’s liberty so they could grab
whatever they could, enslave the debtors and create the polarized society that
Rome became.
JS: OK, but this program worked. The
Republic grew and grew and conquered everyone else for century after century.
Then the Principate became the supreme power in the Western world for several
more centuries.
MH: It worked by looting and stripping other
societies. That can only continue as long as there is some society to loot
and destroy. Once there were no more kingdoms for Rome to destroy, it collapsed
from within. It was basically a looting economy. And it didn’t do more than the
British colonialists did: It only scratched the surface. It didn’t put in place the means of
production that would create enough money for them to grow productively.
Essentially, Rome was a financial
rentier state.
Rentiers don’t create production. They live off existing
production, they don’t create it. That’s why the
classical economists said they were supporting industrial capitalists, not
British landlords, not monopolists and not predatory banks.
JS: This has all been forgotten, both in
the United States and in England —
MH: Let’s say, expurgated from the
curriculum.
JS: Worse than forgotten!
MH: That’s why you don’t have any history
of economic thought taught anymore in the United States. Because then you’d see
that Adam Smith, John Stuart Mill and
the "Ricardian socialists" and indeed most of the 19th century had a completely opposite idea of what
constituted a free market.
JS: Opposite? How so?
MH: Opposite from the neoliberal idea that
freedom means freedom for the wealthy to indebt and destroy the economy.
Opposite from the liberty of Brutus to overthrow the Roman kings and establish
an autocratic oligarchy.
JS: So do we want to see the Roman kings as defenders of the people —
defending them from predatory oligarchs?
MH: Yes, especially Servius Tullius.
There was a great flowering of Rome, making it attractive to immigrants by
making the city livable for newcomers. They did this because at that time, in
the 6th century BC, all societies had a shortage of labor. Labor was the factor of production in short
supply, not land. Not even in Athens was land in short supply in the 6th and
5th centuries. You needed labor, and so you had to make it attractive for
immigrants to join your society instead of having your people run away, as they
would in a society run by creditors reducing clients to bondage.
JS:
So you are writing about how Roman liberty was actually the liberty of
oligarchic creditors from populist pressures for debt forgiveness. What of the
d’ror of Leviticus 25 — the liberty of the postexilic Jews? Did they actually
proclaim years of Jubilee in which debts were forgiven and bondservants were
returned to their families?
MH: After the Babylonian Jews returned to
Jerusalem, I’m sure that they said that it was time for the land to be returned
to its original owners — and their families, by the way, were the original
owners who were exiled in the Babylonian Captivity. I rely largely on Baruch
Levine for this idea of the ge’ullah [?????????], saying give us back our
ancestral lands. [See the colloquium Levine and Hudson co-edited on Land and
Urbanization in the Ancient Near East, and their preceding volume on ancient
privatization.] There must have been some kind of settlement along those lines.
Unfortunately, the Judaic lands did not keep their records on on clay tablets
that could be thrown out and recovered thousands of years later. We don’t have
any record of their economic history after the Return.
JS: Now I’ve brought along the
transcriptions of several Egyptian papyri for you to look at. I also want to
show you a papyrus in Aramaic from Judæa. It’s not direct evidence that the
post-exilic Jews were having Jubilee years, but it’s indirect evidence, because
it says that a particular debt has to be
paid, even during a time of general debt amnesty, even if it falls due in a
shmita [?????], a sabbath year. So it sounds like the Jews were finding loopholes —
MH: It certainly sounds like it! Babylonian creditors tried a similar ploy,
but this was disallowed. (We have court records confirming the realm’s
misharumacts.)
JS: In the Mosaic commandments to forgive
debt, can we infer that there was some sort of program of debt forgiveness in
place already in place in postexilic Jerusalem?
MH: Yes, but it ended with Rabbi Hillel and the Prozbul
clause. Debtors had to sign this clause at the end of their debt contracts
saying that they waived their rights
under the Jubilee year in order to get a loan. That was why Jesus fought
against the Pharisees and the rabbinical leadership. That’s what Luke 4 is all
about [And there was delivered unto him the book of the prophet Isaiah. And when
he had opened the book, he found the place where it was written, "The Spirit of
the Lord is upon me, because he hath anointed me to preach the gospel to the
poor; he hath sent me to heal the brokenhearted, to preach deliverance to the
captives, and recovering of sight to the blind, to set at liberty them that are
bruised, to preach the acceptable year
of the Lord" = the Jubilee
year.] Luke also pointed out that the Pharisees loved money!
JS: Let me ask you about Egypt here.
Unfortunately, as you said, the postexilic Jews did not leave us any clay
tablets and almost no papyri, but we do have loads of papyri concerning the
Ptolemaic kings of Egypt. So from, say, 300 B.C. to the death of Cleopatra, we
have official evidence that the Egyptian
kings proclaimed debt amnesties. Maybe one of the reasons, or perhaps the
main reason for this, is because they were so powerful, like the Mesopotamian
kings. So even though the Ptolemaic
kings were biologically and genetically Macedonian Greek — married to their sisters, too —
they aspired to rule in the ancient Egyptian pharaonic tradition of We Are
God-Kings and We Own Everything in the Kingdom.
MH: Certainly the Hellenistic kings had
the ancient pharaonic Sed festivals,
which go back thousands of years and were a kind of jubilee. The Egyptians had regular debt cancellations,
because under the pharaohs the debts that would have been cancelled were basically tax debts. They were
owed to the crown, so he was cancelling debts owed to himself ultimately. And we
see this thousands of years later in the
trilingual stone, the Rosetta Stone, which the priests wrote for that young
boy who was Ptolemy V. They explained to him that this is how Egypt always had done it,
and to act as a pharaoh, he had to do the same.
JS: And I think it is worth pointing out
here that the same verb-plus-noun combination for forgiving debts that the
priests used in Greek on the Rosetta Stone is also used by Matthew in the Lord’s
Prayer [?f?ken/?feV ?feil?mata, aphe¯ken/aphes opheile¯mata]. It shows up in
lots of papyri. The same Greek verb and noun, again and again and
again.
But let’s go back to the Greeks of the 500s
BC. They are a couple of hundred years out of their Dark Age, so their society
has been reconstituted after the demographic wipeout. It’s been reconstituted,
but without Near Eastern-style "divine kingship" and its Clean Slate
proclamations. Just the opposite. Socrates had conversations with the rhapsodes
who had memorized and recited the Iliad. Even in their great epic, the Greeks’
legendary king of kings Agamemnon comes across as a kind of narcissistic loser.
How would you describe Greek kingship, especially the so-called
tyrants?
MH: There never really were Greek kings of the type
found throughout the Bronze Age Near East and surviving into the first
millennium in Assyria and even in Persia. The Greek polities that emerged
from their Dark Age were run by what
shrewd Classicists call mafiosi,
something like the post-Soviet kleptocrats. They formed closed political monopolies reducing local populations to
clientage and dependency. In one polity after another they were overthrown
and exiled, mainly by aristocratic reformers from the elite families (often
secondary branches, as was Solon). Later
oligarchic writers called them "tyrants" as an invective, much as the word
rex— king —became an invective in oligarchic Rome.
These tyrant-reformers consolidated their power
by redistributing land from the leading families (or in Sparta, land
conquered from Messenia, along with its population reduced to helotage) to the
citizen-army at large all over Greece – except in Athens. That was one of the
most reactionary cities in the 7th century, as shown by what is known about the
laws of Draco. After some abortive coups in the seventh century, Solon was
appointed in 594 to avoid the kind of revolution that had led reformer "tyrants"
to overthrow narrow aristocracies in neighboring Megara and Corinth. Solon decreed a half-way reform, abolishing
debt slavery (but not the debtor’s obligation to work off debts with his own
labor), and did not redistribute Athenian land from the city’s
elites.
Athens was one of the last to reform but
then because it was such a badly polarized autocratic society, it swung — like
Newton’s Third Law of Motion: every action has an equal and opposite reaction —
it swung to become the most democratic of all the Greek polities.
Some historians in the past speculated that
Solon might somehow have been influenced by Judaic law or other Near Eastern
practice, but this is not realistic. I think Solon was simply a pragmatist
responding to widespread demands that he do what the reformers — the so-called
tyrants — were doing throughout Greece. He didn’t redistribute the land like
they did, but he at least ended outright debt slavery. Free debtors (mainly
cultivators on the land) were being seized and sold outside of Athens to slave
dealers. Solon also tried to recover some of the land that wealthy families had
grabbed. At least, that’s what he wrote in his poems describing his
actions.
So to answer your question, I think debt
cancellations were not a diffusionist policy from the East, but a spontaneous
pragmatic response such as was being widely advocated as far west as Rome with
its Secession of the Plebs a century later — followed by much of Greece in the
4th century BC, and Sparta’s kings in the late 3rd century BC.
Poorer Athenians were so angry with Solon for being not revolutionary
enough that he went into exile for 10 years. The
real creators of Athenian democracy were Peisistratos [died 528/7 BC], his sons,
also called tyrants, and then Cleisthenes in 507. He was a member of the wealthy
but outcast family, the Alcmaeonidae, who had been expelled in the 7th century.
Solon had allowed them to return, and they were backed by Delphi (to which the
family contributed heavily). Cleisthenes
fought against the other oligarchic families and restructured Athenian politics on the
basis of locality instead of clan
membership. Servius Tullius is credited for enacting much the same reform in
Rome. Lewis Henry Morgan’s Ancient Society [1877] described this restructuring
of voting districts as the great watershed creation of western-style
democracy.
JS: Let me go back now to the way Athens
and the other poleis emerged from the Dark Age.
MH: Judging from the art and pottery,
Greece didn’t begin to recover until the 8th century BC.
JS: So we’re talking about the 700s BC.
As Greece was learning from the Near
Eastern civilizations, everything from
mythology to the alphabet to weights and measures —
MH:
And commercial practices, credit practices.
JS: Yes, all this came from the Near
East, including the practice of charging interest. But what about Clean Slate
debt amnesty? I want to argue logically here — not from any hard historical
evidence, but only deductively — that the Greeks would have wanted the concept
of Clean Slate debt forgiveness, they would have wanted to learn this too from
the Near East, but they could not do it because they were always going to lack a
Hammurabi-style "divine king."
MH: I think you miss the whole point of
how Western civilization evolved here. First of all, who "wanted" Near Eastern
kingship? Certainly not the emerging oligarchies. The ruling elites wanted to use
interest-bearing debt to enrich themselves – by obtaining control over the labor
power of debtors.
Second, I don’t think the Greeks and Italians knew
about Near Eastern royal proclamations, except as an alien practice much
further East than Asia Minor. Falling into debt was a disaster for the poor, but
a means for their Western patrons to gain power, land and wealth. There is no
record of anyone suggesting that they should be in the Near East. The connection between the Near East and
Greece or Italy was via traders. If you’re a Phoenician or Syrian merchant
with the Aegean or Italy, you’re going to set up a temple as an intermediary,
typically on an island. Such temples
became the cosmopolitan meeting places where you had the oligarchs of the
leading families of Greek cities visiting each other as part of a
Pan-Hellenic group. You could say that Delphi was the "Davos" of its
day.
It was through these trading centers that culture diffused – via the wealthiest
families who travelled and established relationships with other leading
families. Finance and trade have always
been cosmopolitan. These families learned about debt obligations and
contracts from the Near East, and ended up reducing much of their local
populations to clientage, without kings
to overrule them. That would have been the last thing they
wanted.
JS: So absent Hammurabi-style "divine
kingship," is debt bondage and brutal polarization almost inevitably going
to happen in any society that adopts interest-bearing debt?
MH: We see a balance of forces in the
ancient Near East, thanks to the fact that its rulers had authority to cancel
debt and restore land that wealthy individuals had taken from smallholders.
These kings were powerful enough to
prevent the rise of oligarchies that would reduce the population to debt
peonage and bondage (and in the process, deprive the palace of revenue and
corvée labor, and even the military service of debtors owing their labor to
their private creditors). We don’t have any similar protection in today’s
Western Civilization. That’s what separates Western Civilization from the
earlier Near Eastern stage. Modern financialized civilization has stripped away
the power to prevent a land-grabbing creditor oligarchy from controlling society
and its laws.
So you could characterize Western
Civilization is being decadent. It’s reducing populations to austerity on a road
to debt peonage. Today’s new oligarchy
calls this a "free market," but it is the opposite of freedom. You can think
of the Greek and Roman decontextualization of Near Eastern economic regulations
as if the IMF had been put in charge of
Greece and Rome, poisoning its legal and political philosophy at the outset.
So Western Civilization may be just a vast detour. That’s what my forthcoming
book, The Collapse of Antiquity, is all about. That will be the second volume in
my trilogy on the history of debt.
JS: So are we just a vast
detour?
MH: We have to restore a balanced economy
where the oligarchy is controlled, so as to prevent the financial sector from
impoverishing society, imposing austerity and reducing the population to
clientage and debt serfdom.
JS: How do you do that without a
Hammurabi-style "divine kingship"?
MH: You need civil law to do what Near
Eastern kings once did. You need a body of civil law with a strong democratic
government acting to shape markets in society’s overall long-term interest,
not that of the One Percent obtaining wealth by impoverishing the 99 Percent.
You need civil law that protects the population from an oligarchy whose business plan is to
accumulate wealth in ways that impoverish the economy at large. This
requires a body of civil law that would cancel debts when they grow too large
for the population to pay. That probably
requires public banking and credit – in other words, deprivatization of
banking that has become dysfunctional.
All this requires a mixed economy, such as the
Bronze Age Near Eastern economies were. The palace, temples, private sector and
entrepreneurs acted as checks and balances on each other. Western
Civilization isn’t a mixed economy. Socialism was an attempt to create a mixed
economy, but the oligarchs fought back. What they call a "free market" is an
unmixed monolithic, centrally planned financialized economy with freedom for the
oligarchy to impoverish the rest of society. That was achieved by landlordism monopolizing the
land in feudal Europe, and it is done by finance today.
end of part 1
Hudson 2 - Mixed Economy
The Delphic Oracle Was Their Davos: A
Four-Part Interview With Michael
Hudson: Mixed Economies Today, Compared To Those Of Antiquity (Part
2)
Posted on April 3, 2019 by Yves
Smith
By John Siman
John
Siman: Could you define what you mean by a mixed
economy?
Michael Hudson: There are many degrees of
how “mixed” an economy will be — meaning in practice, how active its government
sector will be in regulating markets,
prices and credit, and investing in public infrastructure.
In
the 20th century’s Progressive Era a century ago, a “mixed economy” meant keeping natural monopolies in the public
sector: transportation, the post office, education, health care, and so
forth. The aim was to save the economy from monopoly rent by a either direct
public ownership or government regulation to prevent price gouging by
monopolies.
The
kind of “mixed economy” envisioned by Adam Smith, John Stuart Mill and other
classical 19thcentury free market economists aimed at saving the economy from land rent paid to
Europe’s hereditary landlord class. Either the government would tax away the land’s rent, or would
nationalize it by taking land out of the hands of landlords. The idea was to
free markets from economic rent
(“unearned income”) in general, including monopoly rents, and also to
subsidize basic needs to create a price-competitive national economy.
Long before that, in the Bronze Age — which
I describe in …And Forgive Them Their Debts— the palace reversed the buildup of personal
and agrarian debts by annulling them on a more or less regular basis. This
freed the economy from the overgrowth of debt that tended to build up
chronically from the mathematical dynamics of compound interest, and from crop
failures or other normal “market” phenomenon.
In all these cases a mixed economy was
designed to maintain stability and avoid
exploitation that otherwise would lead to economic polarization.
JS:So a mixed economy is still a market
economy?
MH:
Yes. All these degrees of “mixed
economy” were market economies. But their markets were regulated and subordinated to broad social
and political objectives rather than to personal rent-seeking or creditor
gains. Their economic philosophy was long-term, not short-term, and aimed at
preventing economic imbalance from debt and land monopoly.
Today’s “mixed economy” usually means an active public sector
undertaking investment in infrastructure and controlling money and
credit, and shaping the context of laws within which
the economy operates. This is best understood by contrasting it to what neoliberals call a “pure” or “market”
economy – including what the Trump administration accuses China of when it
proposes countervailing tariffs to shape the U.S. and international market in a
way that favors American corporations and banks.
So it is necessary to clear the
terminological slate before going into more detail. Every economy is a “market
economy” of some sort or another. What is at issue is how large a role governments will play
— specifically, how much it will regulate, how much it will tax, how much it
will invest directly into the economy’s infrastructure and other means of
production or act as a creditor and regulator of the monetary and banking
system.
JS:What can we learn from the mixed
economies of the Ancient Near East? Why were they so prosperous and also stable
for so long?
MH:
The Bronze Age mixed economies of Sumer, Babylonia, Egypt and their Near
Eastern neighbors were subject to “divine kingship,” that is, the ability of
kings to intervene to keep restoring an economy free of personal and rural debt,
so as to maintain a situation where the citizenry on the land was able to serve in the military, provide corvée labor
to create basic infrastructure, and pay fees or taxes to the palace and
temples.
Mesopotamian rulers proclaimed Clean Slates
to keep restoring an idealized status quo ante of free labor (free from debt
bondage). Babylonian rulers had a more
realistic view of the economy than today’s mainstream economists. They
recognized that economies tended to polarize between wealthy creditors and
debtors if what today are called “market forces” are not overridden — especially
the “market forces” of debt, personal liberty or bondage, and land rent. The
task of Bronze Age rulers in their kind of mixed economy was to act from “above”
the market so as to prevent creditors from reducing the king’s subjects (who
were their military defense force) to bondage from appropriating their land
tenure rights. By protecting debtors, strong rulers also prevented creditors
from becoming an oligarchic power in opposition to themselves.
JS:What kind of economic theories and
economic models are the critics of mixed economies trying to advance?
MH: Opponents of a mixed economy have developed
an “equilibrium theory” claiming to show that markets come to a natural, fair
and stable balance without any government “interference.” Their promise is
that if governments will refrain from regulating prices and credit, from
investing and from providing public services, economies will settle naturally at
a highly efficient level. This level will be stable, unless “destabilized” by
government “interference.” Instead of viewing public investment as saving the
economy from monopoly rent and debt peonage, the government itself is described
as a “rent seeker” exploiting and impoverishing the economy.
JS:But is this sort of economic theory
legitimate, or just a libertarian-sounding camouflage for neoliberal
pillage?
MH: It’s Orwellian Doublethink. Today’s neoliberal theory justifies
oligarchies breaking free of public control to appropriate the economic
surplus by indebting economies to skim
off the economic surplus as interest and then foreclose on personal
landholdings and public property, overthrowing “mixed economies” to create a
“pure oligarchy.” Their idea of a free market is one free for creditors and monopolists to deny
economic freedom to the rest of the population. The political extension of
this approach in antiquity was to unseat kings and civic regimes, to concentrate
power in the hands of an increasingly predatory class reducing the economy to
bondage, impoverishing it, and ultimately leaving it to be conquered by
outsiders. That is what happened to Rome
in Late Antiquity.
Advocates of strong government have a diametrically opposite
mathematical model. Ever since the Bronze Age, they
recognized that the “natural” tendency of economies is to polarize between a
wealthy creditor and land-owning class and the rest of society. Bronze Age
rulers recognized that debts tend to
grow faster than the ability to pay (that is, faster than the economy).
Babylonian rulers recognized that if rulers did not intervene to cancel personal
debts (mainly agrarian debts by
cultivators) when crops failed, when military action interfered, or simply
when debts built up over time, then creditors would end up taking the crop
surplus and even the labor services of debtors as interest, and finally
foreclosing on the land. This would have deprived the palatial economy of land
and labor contributions. And by enriching an independent class of creditors (on
their way to becoming large landowners) outside of the palace, financial wealth would express itself in
economic and even military power. An incipient financial and landholding
oligarchy would mount its own military and political campaign to unseat rulers
and dismantle the mixed palatial/private economy to create one that was owned
and controlled by oligarchies.
The result in Classical Antiquity was
economic polarization leading to austerity and bondage, grinding the economy to
a halt. That is the tendency of economies in “unmixed” economies where the
public sector is privatized and economic regulation is dismantled. Land and
credit was monopolized and smallholders became dependent clients and ultimately
were replaced by slaves.
Mixed economies by the late 19th century aimed at minimizing market
prices for real estate and monopoly goods, and for credit. The economic aim was to minimize the cost of living and doing
business so as to make economies more productive. This was called “socialism” as the
natural outgrowth of industrial capitalism protecting itself from the most
burdensome legacies of feudalism: an absentee landlord class, and a banking
class whose money-lending was not productive but predatory.
JS:So mixed economies require strong and
ultimately good governments.
MH: Any “mixed” economy has some basic
economic theory of what the proper role of government is. At the very least, as
in the 20th century, this included the limitation of monopoly rents. The
neoclassical (that is, anti-classical) reaction was to formulate a euphemistic
theory of consumer “demand” — as if American consumers “demand” to pay high
prices for pharmaceuticals and health care. Likewise in the case of housing
prices for renters or, for owner-occupied housing, mortgage charges: Do renters
and home buyers really “demand” to pay higher and higher rents and larger and
larger mortgages? Or are they compelled to pay out of need, paying whatever
their suppliers demand (e.g., as in “Your money or your
life/health”).
So to answer your question, a mixed economy
is one in which governments and society at large realize that economies need to
be regulated and monopolies (headed by credit and land ownership) kept out of
the hands of private rent-seekers in order to keep the economy free and
efficient.
JS: Has there ever been a civil society
that effectively implemented a mixed economy since, say, 500 BC?
MH: All successful economies have been
mixed economies. And the more “mixed” they are, the more successful, stable and
long-lasting they have been as a result of their mutual public/private checks
and balances.
America was a mixed economy in the late 19th century. It became the world’s most successful industrial economy because it
didn’t have an absentee landlord class
like Europe did (except for the railroad octopus), and it enacted protective tariffs to endow a domestic
manufacturing class to catch up with and overtake England.
JS: Other countries?
MH: Germany began to be a mixed economy in the
decades leading up to World War I. But it had a mentally retarded king whom
they didn’t know how to restrain, given their cultural faith in royalty. China is of course the most successful
recent mixed economy.
JS: Isn’t it pretty brutal in China for
most of the population?
MH: Most of the population does not find
it brutal there. It was brutal under
colonialism and later still, under Mao’s Cultural Revolution. But now, most
people in China seem to want to get rich. That’s why you’re having a
consolidation period of trying to get rid of the local corruption, especially in
the rural areas. You’re seeing a consolidation period that requires clamping
down on a lot of people who became successful through shady
operations.
JS: So how would you describe an ideal
society without a Hammurabi-style “divine kingship”? An ideal mixed
economy?
MH: The credit system would be public.
That way, public banks could create
credit for socially productive purposes — and could cancel the occasional
overgrowth of debts without causing private creditors to lose and protest. The
public sector also would own and operate
the natural infrastructure monopolies. That was the basic principle of
classical economics from Adam Smith to Marx, even for erstwhile libertarians
such as Henry George. Everybody in the
19th century expected a mixed economy with governments playing a growing
role, replacing absentee landlords, bankers and monopolists with public
collection of economic rent, public control of the credit system and provider of
basic needs.
JS: How extensive should the public
sector be?
MH: A classical public sector would
include the natural monopolies that otherwise would engage in price gouging,
especially the credit and banking system. These sectors should be public in
character. For one thing, only a public
bank can write down the debts — like student debts today — without hurting
an independent oligarchic financial class. If student debts and mortgage debts
were owed to public banks, they could be written down in keeping with the
reasonable ability to be paid. Also, public banks wouldn’t make junk mortgage
loans to NINJA borrowers, as did Citibank and the other crooked banks. A public bank wouldn’t make predatory
corporate raiding and takeover loans, or finance and speculate in derivative gambles.
Most
of all, when the debt overhead becomes too large — when a large corporation that
is essential to the economy can’t pay its debts —public banks can write down the debt so
that the company isn’t forced into bankruptcy and sold to an American vulture
fund or other vulture fund. It can keep operating. In China the government
provides this essential service of public banks.
The key public concern throughout history
has been to prevent debt from crippling society. That aim is what Babylonian and
other third-millennium and second-millennium Near Eastern rulers recognized
clearly enough, with their mathematical models. To make an ideal society you
need the government to control the basic utilities — land, finance, mineral
wealth, natural resources and infrastructure monopolies (including the Internet
today), pharmaceuticals and health care so their basic services can be supplied
at the lowest price.
All
this was spelled out in the 19th century by business school analysts in the
United States. Simon Patten [1852-1922]
who said that public investment is the “fourth factor of production.” But
its aim isn’t to make a profit for itself. Rather, it’s to lower the cost of
living and of doing business, by providing basic needs either on a subsidized
basis or for free. The aim was to create
a low-cost society without a rentier class siphoning off unearned income and
making this economic rent a hereditary burden on the economy at large. You want
to prevent unearned income.
To do that, you need a concept to define
economic rent as unearned and hence unnecessary income. A well-managed economy
would do what Adam Smith, David Ricardo, John Stuart Mill, Marx and Veblen
recommended: It would prevent a hereditary rentier class living off unearned
income and increasing society’s economic overhead. It’s okay to make a profit, but not to make
extractive monopoly rent, land rent or financial usury rent.
JS: Will human beings ever create such a
society?
MH: If they don’t, we’re going to have a
new Dark Age.
JS: That’s one thing that especially
surprises me about the United States. Is it not clear to educated people here
that our ruling class is fundamentally extractive and exploitative?
MH: A lot of these educated people are
part of the ruling class, and simply taking their money and running. They are
disinvesting, not investing in industry. They’re saying, “The financial rentier
game is ending, so let’s sell everything and maybe buy a farm in New Zealand to
go to when there is a big war.” So the
financial elite is quite aware that they are getting rich by running the economy
into the ground, and that this must end at the point where they’ve taken
everything and left a debt-ridden shell behind.
JS: I guess this gets back to what you
were saying: The history of economics has been expurgated from the
curriculum.
MH: Once you strip away economic history
and the history of economic thought, you
wipe out memory of the vocabulary that people have used to criticize rent
seeking and other unproductive activity. You then are in a position to redefine words and ideals along the lines
that euphemize predatory and parasitic activities as if they are productive
and desirable, even natural. You can rewrite history to suppress the idea that
all this is the opposite of what Adam Smith and the classical economists down
through Marx advocated.
Today’s neoliberal wasteland is basically a
reaction against the 19th century reformers, against the logic of classical
British political economy. The hatred of Marx is ultimately the hatred of Adam
Smith and John Stuart Mill, because neoliberals realize that Smith and Mill and
Ricardo were all leading to Marx. He was the culmination of their free market
views — a market free from rentiers and monopolists.
That was the immediate aim of socialism in
the late 19th century. The logic of classical political economy was leading to
a socialist mixed economy. In order
to fight Marxism, you have to fight classical economics and erase memory of how
civilization has dealt with (or failed to deal with) the debt and
rent-extracting problems through the ages. The history of economic thought and
the original free-market economics has to be suppressed. Today’s choice is therefore between socialism or
barbarism, as Rosa Luxemburg said.
JS: Let’s consider barbarism: When I
observe the neoliberal ruling class — the people who control the finance sector
and the managerial class on Wall Street — I often wonder if they’re historically
exceptional because they’ve gone beyond simple greed and lust for wealth. They
now seek above all some barbaric and sadistic pleasure in the financial
destruction and humiliation of other people. Or is this historically
normal?
MH: The financial class has always lived
in the short run, and you can make
short-term money much quicker by asset stripping and being predatory can by
being productive. Moses Finley wrote that there was not a single productive loan
in all of Antiquity. That was quite an overstatement, but he was making the
point that there were no productive financial markets in Antiquity. Almost all
manufacturing, industry, and agriculture was self-financed. So the reader of
Finley likely infers that we modern people have progressed in a fundamental way
beyond Antiquity. They were characterized by the homo politicus, greedy for
status. We have evolved into homo œconomicus, savvy enough to live in stable
safety and comfort.
We are supposedly the beneficiaries of the
revolution of industrial capitalism, as if all the predatory, polarizing,
usurious lending that you had from feudal times (and before that, from
Antiquity), was replaced by productive lending that finances means of production
and actual economic growth.
But in reality, modern banks don’t lend money for
production. They say, “That’s the job of the stock market.” Banks only lend if
there’s collateral to grab. They lend against assets in place. So the result of more bank lending is to increase
the price of the assets that banks lend against — on credit! This way of
“wealth creation” via asset-price inflation is the opposite of real substantive
progress. It enriches the narrow class of asset holders at the top of the
economic pyramid.
JS: What about the stock
market?
MH: The stock market no longer primarily provides
money for capital investment. It has become a vehicle for bondholders and
corporate raiders to borrow from banks and private funds to buy corporate
stockholders, take the companies private, downsize them, break them up or strip
their assets, and borrow more to buy back their stocks to create asset-price
gains without increasing the economy’s tangible real asset base. So the
financial sector, except for a brief period in the late 19th century, especially
in Germany, has rarely financed productive growth. Financial engineering has
replaced industrial engineering, just as in Antiquity’s creditors were asset
strippers.
The one productive activity that the
financial sector engaged in from the Bronze Age onward was to finance foreign
trade. The original interest-bearing
debt was owed by merchants to reimburse their silent partners, typically the palace or the temples, and in time
wealthy individuals. But apart from financing trade – in products that were
already produced – you’ve rarely had finance increase the means of production or
economic growth. It’s almost always been
to extract income. The income that finance extracts is at the expense of the
rest of society. So the richer the financial sector is, the more austerity is
imposed on the non-financial sector.
JS: That’s pretty depressing.
MH: When I did the show with Jimmy Dore
[https://www.youtube.com/watch?v=PSvcB55R8jM],
he saw that the most important dynamic to understand is that debts grow more
rapidly than the economy at large. The
rate of interest is higher than the rate of growth. It may not be higher
than the profit rate, but it’s higher than the rate of growth. So every society
that has interest-bearing debt is going to end up deeper and deeper in debt. At
a certain point the creditors are paid at the expense of production and
investment — and soon enough they foreclose.
JS: And then?
MH: Then you have debt deflation. That is the norm.
Austerity. It is not an anomaly, but the essence. The Babylonians knew this, and they tried to
avoid debt deflation by wiping out the predatory personal debts, not the
business debts that were commercial and productive. Only the non-commercial debts were wiped
out.
JS: How could Modern Monetary Theory be used now,
effectively?
MH: The main way is to say that governments don’t have to borrow at
interest from existing financial “savers,” mainly the One Percent. The
government can do what America did during the Civil War: print greenbacks. (The MMT version is the Trillion-dollar platinum
coin.) The Treasury can provide the money needed by the economy. It does
that by running a budget deficit and spending money into the economy. If you
don’t do that, if you do what Bill Clinton did in the last years of his
presidency and run a budget surplus, then you force the economy to depend on
banks for credit.
The
problem is that bank credit is essentially predatory and extractive. The same
thing happens in Europe. The Eurozone governments cannot run a budget deficit of
more than 3 percent, so the government is unable to spend enough money to invest
in public infrastructure or anything else. As a result, the Eurozone economy is
subject to debt deflation, which is exacerbated by people having to borrow from
the banks at high interest rates that far exceeds the rate of growth. So Europe
is suffering an even more serious debt deflation than the United
States.
JS: Is any of this going to change,
either in Europe or here?
MH: Not until there’s a crash. Not until
it gets serious enough that people realize that there has to be an alternative.
Right now Margaret Thatcher and the neoliberals have won. She said there was no
alternative, and as long as people believe There Is No Alternative, they’re not
going to realize that it doesn’t have to be this way, and that you don’t need a private banking sector. A
public banking sector would be much more efficient.
JS: How would you sum up Wall Street
right now? Is it entirely predatory? Entirely parasitical? What are Wall
Street’s essential functions now?
MH: Number one, to run a casino. By far
the largest volume at stake is betting on whether interest rates, foreign
exchange rates or stock prices will go up or down. So the financial system has turned into a
gambling casino. Its second aim is to load the economy down with as much
debt as possible. Debt is the banking
system’s “product,” and the GDP
counts its “carried interest” penalties and late fees, its short-term trading
gains as “financial services” counted as part of Gross Domestic Product
(GDP).
The aim is to get as much of these financial
returns as possible, and finally to
foreclose on as much property of defaulting debtors as possible. The
business plan — as I learned at Chase Manhattan years ago — is to transfer all economic growth into the hands
of financial investors, the One Percent. The financial business plan is to
create a set of laws and mount a campaign of regulatory capture so that all the
growth in the economy accrues to the One Percent, not the 99 Percent. That means
that as the One Percent’s rentier income grows, the 99 Percent gets less and
less each year, until finally it emigrates or dies off, or is put into a
for-profit prison, which looks like a growth industry today.
JS: Is there a single good thing that
Wall Street does? Is there anything good that comes out of Wall
Street?
MH: You have to look at it as a system.
You can’t segregate a particular action from the overall economy. If the overall
system aims at making money in predatory ways at somebody else’s expense, then
it is a zero-sum game. That is essentially a short-run business model. And
politically, it involves opposing a mixed economy. At least, the “old fashioned” socialist mixed economy
in which governments subordinate short-term gain-seeking to long-term objectives
uplifting the entire economy.
As the Greek philosophers recognized,
wealthy people define their power by their ability to injure the rest of
society, so as to lord it over them. That was the Greek philosophy of money-lust
[πleonex?a, pleonexia] and hubris [?briV] — not merely arrogance, but behavior
that was injurious to others.
Rentier
income is injurious to society at large. Rentiersdefine a “free market”
as one in which they are free to deny economic freedom to their customers,
employees and other victims. The rentier model is to enrich the oligarchy to a
point where it is able to capture the government.
end of part 2
Hudson Part 3
The Delphic Oracle Was Their Davos: A
Four-Part Interview With Michael
Hudson: The Inherent Financial Instability in Western Civilization’s DNA
(Part 3)
Posted on April 4, 2019 by Yves
Smith
By John Siman, who is also the author of
Part 1 and Part 2 in this series
John
Siman: It seems that unless there’s a
Hammurabi-style "divine king" or some elected civic regulatory authority,
oligarchies will arise and exploit their societies as much as they can, while
trying to prevent the victimized economy from defending itself.
Michael Hudson: Near Eastern rulers kept
credit and land ownership subordinate to the aim of maintaining overall growth
and balance. They prevented creditors from turning citizens into indebted
clients obliged to work off their debts instead of serving in the military,
providing corvée labor and paying crop rents or other fees to the palatial
sector.
JS: So looking at history going back to
2000 or 3000 BC, once we no longer have the powerful Near Eastern "divine
kings," there seems not to have been a stable and free economy. Debts kept
mounting up to cause political revolts. In Rome, this started with the Secession of
the Plebs in 494 BC, a century after Solon’s debt cancellation resolved a
similar Athenian crisis.
MH: Near Eastern debt cancellations continued into the
Neo-Assyrian and Neo-Babylonian Empires in the first millennium BC, and also
into the Persian Empire. Debt amnesties and laws protecting debtors
prevented the debt slavery that is found in Greece and Rome. What modern
language would call the Near Eastern "economic model" recognized that economies
tended to become unbalanced, largely as a result of buildup of debt and various
arrears on payments. Economic survival in fact required an ethic of growth and
rights for the citizenry (who manned the army) to be self-supporting without
running into debt and losing their economic liberty and personal freedom. Instead of the West’s ultimate drastic
solution of banning interest, rulers cancelled the buildup of personal debts
to restore an idealized order "as it was in the beginning."
This ideology has always needed to be
sanctified by religion or at least by democratic ideology in order to prevent
the predatory privatization of land, credit, and ultimately the government.
Greek philosophy warned against monetary greed [πleonex?a,pleonexia] and
money-love [filocrhmat?a, philochrêmatia] from Sparta’s mythical lawgiver
Lycurgus to Solon’s poems describing his debt cancellation in 594 and the
subsequent philosophy of Plato and Socrates, as well as the plays of
Aristophanes. The Delphic Oracle warned
that money-love was the only thing that could destroy Sparta [Diodorus
Siculus 7.5]. That indeed happened after
404 BC when the war with Athens ended and foreign tribute poured into Sparta’s
almost un-monetized regulated economy.
The problem, as famously described in The
Republic and handed down in Stoic philosophy, was how to prevent a wealthy class
from becoming wealth-addicted, hubristic and injurious to society. The 7th-century "tyrants" were followed by
Solon in Athens in banning luxuries and public shows of wealth, most
notoriously at funerals for one’s ancestors. Socrates went barefoot [?nuπ?dhtoV,
anupodêtos] to show his contempt for wealth, and hence his freedom from its
inherent personality defects. Yet despite this universal ideal of avoiding
extremes, oligarchic rule became economically polarizing and destructive,
writing laws to make its creditor claims and the loss of land by smallholders
irreversible. That was the opposite of Near Eastern Clean Slates and their
offshoot, Judaism’s Jubilee Year.
JS: So despite the ideals of their
philosophy, Greek political systems had no function like that of Hammurabi-like
kings — or philosopher-kings for that matter — empowered to hold financial
oligarchies in check. This state of affairs led philosophers to develop an
economic tradition of lamentation instead. Socrates, Plato and Aristotle, Livy and
Plutarch bemoaned the behavior of the money-loving oligarchy. But they did not develop a program to rectify
matters. The best they could do was to inspire and educate individuals —
most of whom were their wealthy students and readers. As you said, they
bequeathed a legacy of Stoicism. Seeing that the problem was not going to be
solved in their lifetimes, they produced a beautiful body of literature praising
philosophical virtue.
MH: The University of Chicago, where I
was an undergraduate in the 1950s, focused on Greek philosophy. We read Plato’s
Republic, but they skipped over the discussion of wealth-addiction. They talked
about philosopher-kings without explaining that Socrates’ point was that rulers must not
own land and other wealth, so as not to have the egotistical tunnel vision
that characterized creditors monopolizing control over land and
labor.
JS: In Book 8 of the Republic, Socrates
condemns oligarchies as being characterized by an insatiable greed
[?πlhst?a,aplêstia] for money and specifically criticizes them for allowing
polarization between the super-rich [?π?rπloutoi, hyper-ploutoi] and the poor
[π?nhteV, penêtes], who are made utterly resourceless [?πoroi,
aporoi].
MH: One needs to know the context of
Greek economic history in order to understand The Republic’s main concern. Popular demands for land redistribution and
debt cancellation were resisted with increasing violence. Yet few histories
of Classical Antiquity focus on this financial dimension of the distribution of
land, money and wealth.
Socrates said that if you let the wealthiest landowners and creditors
become the government, they’re probably going to be
wealth-addicted and turn the government
into a vehicle to help them exploit the rest of society. There was no idea
at Chicago of this central argument made by Socrates about rulers falling
subject to wealth-addiction. The word "oligarchy" never came up in my
undergraduate training, and the "free market" business school’s Ayn Rand philosophy of selfishness is
as opposite from Greek philosophy as it is from Judeo-Christian
religion.
JS: The word "oligarchy" comes up a lot
in book 8 of Plato’s Republic. Here are 3 passages:
1. At Stephanus page 550c … "And what kind
of a regime," said he, "do you understand by oligarchy [?ligarc?a]?" "That based
on a property qualification," said I, "wherein the rich [πlo?sioi] hold office
[550d] and the poor man [π?nhV, penês] is excluded.
2. at 552a … "Consider now whether this
polity [i.e. oligarchy] is not the first that admits that which is the greatest
of all such evils." "What?" "The allowing a man to sell all his possessions,
which another is permitted to acquire, and after selling them to go on living in
the city, but as no part of it, neither a money-maker, nor a craftsman, nor a
knight, nor a foot-soldier, but classified only as a pauper [π?nhV, penês] and a
dependent [?πoroV, aporos]." [552b] "This is the first," he said. "There
certainly is no prohibition of that sort of thing in oligarchical states.
Otherwise some of their citizens would not be excessively rich [?π?rπloutoi,
hyper-ploutoi], and others out and out paupers [π?nhteV, penêtes]."
3 at 555b: "Then," said I, "is not the transition from oligarchy to democracy
effected in some such way as this — by the insatiate greed [?πlhst?a, aplêstia]
for that which oligarchy set before itself as the good, the attainment of the
greatest possible wealth?"
MH: By contrast, look where Antiquity
ended up by the 2nd century BC. Rome physically devastated Athens, Sparta,
Corinth and the rest of Greece. By the Mithridatic Wars (88-63 BC) their temples
were looted and their cities driven into unpayably high debt to Roman tax
collectors and Italian moneylenders. Subsequent Western civilization developed
not from the democracy in Athens but from oligarchies supported by Rome.
Democratic states were physically destroyed, blocking civic regulatory power and
imposing pro-creditor legal principles making foreclosures and forced land sales
irreversible.
JS:It seems that Greek and Roman
Antiquity could not solve the problem of economic polarization. That makes me
want to ask about our own country: To what extent does America resemble Rome
under the emperors?
MH:Wealthy families have always tried to
break "free" from central political power — free to destroy the freedom of
people they get into debt and take their land and property. Successful societies
maintain balance. That requires public power to check and reverse the excesses
of personal wealth seeking, especially debt secured by the debtor’s labor and
land or other means of self-support. Balanced societies need the power to
reverse the tendency of debts to grow faster than the ability to be paid. That
tendency runs like a red thread through Greek and Roman history.
This overgrowth of debt is also
destabilizing today’s U.S. and other financialized economies. Banking and financial interests have broken
free of tax liability since 1980, and are enriching themselves not by
helping the overall economy grow and raising living standards, but just the
opposite: by getting the bulk of society into debt to themselves.
This financial class is also indebting
governments and taking payment in the form of privatizing the public domain.
(Greece is a conspicuous recent example.) This road to privatization,
deregulation and un-taxing of wealth really took off with Margaret Thatcher and
Ronald Reagan cheerleading the anti-classical philosophy of Frederick von Hayek and the anti-classical economics of
Milton Friedman and the Chicago Boys.
Something much like this happened in Rome.
Arnold Toynbee described its oligarchic
land grab that endowed its ruling aristocracy with unprecedented wealth as
Hannibal’s Revenge. That was the main
legacy of Rome’s Punic Wars with Carthage ending around 200 BC. Rome’s
wealthy families who had contributed their jewelry and money to the war effort,
made their power grab and said that what originally appeared to be patriotic
contributions should be viewed as having been a loan. The Roman treasury was
bare, so the government (controlled by
these wealthy families) gave them public land, the ager publicus that
otherwise would have been used to settle war veterans and other
needy.
Once you inherit wealth, you tend to think
that it’s naturally yours, not part of society’s patrimony for mutual aid. You
see society in terms of yourself, not yourself as part of society. You become
selfish and increasingly predatory as the economy shrinks as a result of your
indebting it and monopolizing its land and property. You see yourself as
exceptional, and justify this by thinking of yourself as what Donald Trump would
call "a winner," not subject to the rules of "losers," that is, the rest of
society. That’s a major theme in Greek philosophy from Socrates and Plato and
Aristotle through the Stoics. They saw an inherent danger posed by an
increasingly wealthy landholding and creditor ruling class atop an indebted
population at large. If you let such a class emerge independently of social
regulation and checks on personal egotism and hubris, the economic and political
system becomes predatory. Yet that has been the history of Western
civilization.
Lacking a tradition of subordinating debt
and land foreclosure from smallholders, the Greek and Italian states that
emerged in the 7th century BC took a different political course from the Near
East. Subsequent Western civilization lacked a regime of oversight to alleviate
debt problems and keep the means of self-support broadly distributed.
The social democratic movements that
flowered from the late 19th century until the 1980s sought to re-create such
regulatory mechanisms, as in Teddy
Roosevelt’s trust busting, the income tax, Franklin Roosevelt’s New Deal,
postwar British social democracy. But these moves to reverse economic
inequality and polarization are now being rolled back, causing austerity, debt
deflation and the concentration of wealth at the top of the economic pyramid. As
oligarchies take over government, they lorded it over the rest of society much
like feudal lords who emerged from the wreckage of the Roman Empire in the
West.
The tendency is for political power to
reflect wealth. Rome’s constitution weighted voting power in proportion to one’s
landholdings, minimizing the voting power of the non-wealthy. Today’s private
funding of political campaigns in the United States is more indirect in shifting
political power to the Donor Class, away from the Voting Class. The effect is to
turn governments to serve a financial and property-owning class instead of
prosperity for the economy at large. We thus are in a position much like that of
Rome in 509 BC, when the kings were overthrown by an oligarchy claiming to
"free" their society from any power able to control the wealthy. The call for
"free markets" today is for deregulation of rentier wealth, turning the economy
into a free-for-all.
Classical Greece and Italy had a fatal flaw:
From their inception they had no tradition of a mixed public/private economy
such as characterized in the Near East, whose palatial economy and temples
produced the main economic surplus and infrastructure. Lacking royal overrides,
the West never developed policies to prevent a creditor oligarchy from reducing
the indebted population to debt bondage, and foreclosing on the land of
smallholders. Advocates of debt amnesties were accused of "seeking kingship" in
Rome, or aspiring to "tyranny"(in Greece).
JS:It seems to me that you’re saying this
economic failure is Antiquity’s original sin as well as fatal flaw. We have
inherited a great philosophic and literary tradition from them analyzing and
lamenting this failure, but without a viable program to set it right.
MH:That insight unfortunately has been
stripped out of the curriculum of classical studies, just as the economics
discipline sidesteps the phenomenon of wealth addiction. If you take an
economics course, the first thing you’re taught in price theory is diminishing
marginal utility: The more of anything you have, the less you need it or enjoy
it. You can’t enjoy consuming it beyond a point. But Socrates and Aristophanes
emphasized, accumulating money is not like eating bananas, chocolate or any
other consumable commodity. Money is different because, as Socrates said, it is
addictive, and soon becomes an insatiable desire [?πlhst?a,
aplêstia].
JS:Yes, I understand! Bananas are
fundamentally different from money because you can get sick of bananas, but you
can never have too much money! In your forthcoming book, The Collapse of
Antiquity, you quote what Aristophanes says in his play Plutus (the god of
wealth and money). The old man Chremylus — his name is based on the Greek word
for money, chrêmata[cr?mata] — Chremylus and his slave perform a duet in praise
of Plutus as the prime cause of everything in the world, reciting a long list.
The point is that money is a singular special thing: "O Money-god, people never
get sick of your gifts. They get tired of everything else; they get tired of
love and bread, of music and honors, of treats and military advancement, of
lentil soup, etc., etc. But they never get tired of money. If a man has thirteen
talents of silver — 13 million dollars, say — he wants sixteen; and if he gets
sixteen, he will want forty, and so forth, and he will complain of being short
of cash the whole time."
MH: Socrates’s problem was to figure out
a way to have government that did not serve the wealthy acting in socially
destructive ways. Given that his student Platowas an aristocrat and that Plato’s
students in the Academy werearistocratsas well, how can you have a government
run by philosopher-kings? Socrates’s solution was not practical at that time:
Rulers should not have money or property. But all governments were based on the
property qualification, so his proposal for philosopher-kings lacking wealth was
utopian. And like Plato and other Greek aristocrats, they disapproved of debt
cancellations, accusing these of being promoted by populist leaders seeking to
become tyrants.
JS:Looking over the broad sweep of Roman
history, your book describes how, century after century, oligarchs were whacking
every energetic popular advocate whose policies threatened their monopoly of
political power, and their economic power as creditors and privatizers of the
public domain, Rome’s ager publicus, for themselves.
I brought with me on the train Cæsar’s
Gallic War. What do you think of Cæsar and how historians have interpreted his
role?
MH:The late 1st century BC was a
bloodbath for two generations before Cæsar was killed by oligarchic senators. I
think his career exemplifies what Aristotle said of aristocracies turning into
democracies: He sought to take the majority of citizens into their own camp to
oppose the aristocratic monopolies of landholding, the courts and political
power.
Cæsar sought to ameliorate the oligarchic Senate’s worst abuses that
were stifling Rome’s economy and even much of the
aristocracy. Mommsen is the most famous historian describing how rigidly and
unyieldingly the Senate opposed democratic attempts to achieve a role in
policy-making for the population at large, or to defend the debtors losing their
land to creditors, who were running the government for their own personal
benefit. He described how Sulla strengthened the oligarchy against Marius, and
Pompey backed the Senate against Caesar. But competition for the consulship and
other offices was basically just a personal struggle among rival individuals,
not rival concrete political programs. Roman politics was autocratic from the
very start of the Republic when the aristocracy overthrew the kings in 509 BC.
Roman politics during the entire Republic was a fight by the oligarchy against
democracy and the populace as a whole.
The patricians used violence to "free"
themselves from any public authority able to check their own monopoly of power,
money and land acquisition by expropriating smallholders and grabbing the public
domain being captured from neighboring peoples.
Roman history from one century to the next is a narrative of killing
advocates of redistributing public land to the people instead of letting it be
grabbed by the patricians, or who called for a debt cancellation or even just an
amelioration of the cruel debts laws.
On the one hand, Mommsen idolized Cæsar as
if he were a kind of revolutionary democrat. But given the oligarchy’s total
monopoly on political power and force, Mommsen recognized that under these
conditions there could not be any political solution to Rome’s economic
polarization and impoverishment. There could only be anarchy or a dictatorship.
So Caesar’s role was that of a Dictator — vastly outnumbered by his
opposition.
A generation before Caesar, Sulla seized power
militarily, bringing his army to conquer Rome and making himself Dictator in
82 BC. He drew up a list of his populist opponents to be murdered and their
estates confiscated by their killers. He
was followed by Pompey, who could have become a dictator but didn’t have much
political sense, so Caesar emerged victorious. Unlike Sulla or Pompey, he
sought a more reformist policy to check the senatorial corruption and
self-dealing.
The oligarchic Senate’s only "political
program" was opposition to "kingship" or any such power able to check its land
grabbing and corruption. The oligarchs assassinated him, as they had killed
Tiberius and Gaius Gracchus in 133 and 121, the praetor Asellio who sought to
alleviate the population’s debt burden in 88 by trying to enforce pro-creditor
laws, and of course the populist advocates of debt cancellation such as Catiline
and his supporters. Would-be reformers were assassinated from the very start of
the Republic after the aristocracy overthrew Rome’s kings.
JS:If Caesar had been successful, what
kind of ruler might he have been?
MH:In many ways he was like the
reformer-tyrants of the 7th and 6th centuries in Corinth, Megara and other Greek
cities. They all were members of the ruling elite. He tried to check the
oligarchy’s worst excesses and land grabs, and like Catiline, Marius and the
Gracchi brothers before him, to ameliorate the problems faced by debtors. But by
his time the poorer Romans already had lost their land, so the major debts were
owed by wealthier landowners. His bankruptcy law only benefited the well-to-do
who had bought land on credit and could not pay their moneylenders as Rome’s
long Civil War disrupted the economy. The poor already had been ground down.
They supported him mainly for his moves toward democratizing politics at the
expense of the Senate.
JS: After his assassination we get Caesar’s heir Octavian, who becomes
Augustus. So we have the official end of the Republic and the beginning of a
long line of emperors, the Principate. Yet despite the Senate’s authority being
permanently diminished, there is continued widening of economic polarization. Why couldn’t the Emperors save
Rome?
MH:Here’s an analogy for you: Just as
nineteenth-century industrial reformers thought that capitalism’s political role
was to reform the economy by stripping away the legacy of feudalism — a
hereditary landed aristocracy and predatory financial system based mainly on
usury — what occurred was not an evolution of industrial capitalism into
socialism. Instead, industrial
capitalism turned into finance capitalism. In Rome you had the end of the
senatorial oligarchy followed not by a powerful, debt-forgiving central
authority (as Mommsen believed that Caesar was moving toward, and as many Romans
hoped that he was moving towards), but to an even more polarized imperial
garrison state.
JS:That’s indeed what happened. The
emperors who ruled in the centuries after Cæsar insisted on being deified — they
were officially "divine," according to their own propaganda. Didn’t any of them
have the potential power to reverse the Roman economy’s ever-widening
polarization of the, like the Near Eastern "divine kings" from the third
millennium BC into the Neo-Assyrian, Neo-Babylonian and even the Persian Empire
in the first millennium?
MH:The inertia of Rome’s status quo and
vested interests among patrician nobility was so strong that emperors didn’t
have that much power. Most of all, they
didn’t have a conceptual intellectual framework for changing the economy’s basic
structure as economic life became de-urbanized and shifted to self-sufficient quasi-feudal manor
estates. Debt amnesties and protection of small self-sufficient tax-paying
landholders as the military base was achieved only in the Eastern Roman
Empire, in Byzantium under the 9th– and
10th-century emperors (as I’ve described in my history of debt cancellations
in …And Forgive Them Their Debts).
The
Byzantine emperors were able to do what Western Roman emperors could not.
They reversed the expropriation of
smallholders and annulled their debts in order to keep a free tax-paying citizenry able to
serve in the army and provide public labor duties. But by the 11th and
12thcenturies, Byzantium’s prosperity enabled its oligarchy to create private
armies of their own to fight against centralized authority able to prevent their
grabbing of land and labor.
It seems that Rome’s late kings did
something like this. That is what attracted immigrants to Rome and fueled its
takeoff. But with prosperity came rising power of patrician families, who moved
to unseat the kings. Their rule was followed by a depression and walkouts by the
bulk of the population to try and force better policy. But that could no be
achieved without democratic voting power, so faith was put in personal leader —
subject to patrician violence to abort any real economic democracy.
In Byzantium’s case, the tax-avoiding oligarchy weakened the
imperial economy to the point where the Crusaders were able to loot and
destroy Constantinople. Islamic invaders were then able to pick up the
pieces.
The most relevant point of studying history
today should be how the economic conflict between creditors and debtors affected
the distribution of land and money. Indeed, the tendency of a wealthy overclass
to pursue self-destructive policies that impoverish society should be what
economic theory is all about. We’ll discuss this in Part 4.
end of part 3
The Delphic Oracle Was Their Davos: A
Four-Part Interview With Michael
Hudson: A New "Reality Economics" Curriculum Is Needed (Part 4)
Posted on April 5, 2019 by Yves Smith
By John Siman, who is also the author of
Part 1, Part 2, and Part 3 in this series
John
Siman:I want to spell out the implications of the
points that Socrates brought up, and with which you and I agree. That leaves the
question facing us today: Is the American oligarchy and state as rapacious as
that of Rome? Or is it universally the nature of oligarchy in any historical
setting to be rapacious? And if so,
where is it all leading?
Michael Hudson: If Antiquity had followed
the "free market" policies of modern neoliberal economics, the Near East, Greece
and Rome would never have gained momentum. Any such "free market" avoiding
mutual aid and permitting a wealthy class to emerge and enslave the bulk of the
population by getting it into debt and taking its land would have shrunk, or
been conquered from without or by revolution from within. That’s why the
revolutions of the 7thcentury BC, led to reformers subsequently called "tyrants"
in Greece (and "kings" in Rome) were necessary to attract populations rather
than reduce them to bondage.
So of course it is hard for mainstream
economists to acknowledge that Classical Antiquity fell because it failed to
regulate and tax the wealthy financial and landowning classes, and failed to
respond to popular demands to cancel personal debts and redistribute the land
that had been monopolized by the wealthy.
The wealth of the Greek and Roman
oligarchies was the ancient counterpart to today’s Finance, Insurance and Real
Estate (FIRE) sector, and their extractive and predatory behavior is what
destroyed Antiquity. The perpetuation of this problem even today, two thousand
years later, should establish that the debt/credit dynamic and polarization of
wealth is a central problem of Western civilization.
JS: So what were — and are — the
political and social dynamic at work?
MH: The key is the concept of wealth
addiction and how it leads to hubris — arrogance that seeks to increase power in
ways that hurt other people. Hubris is not merely over-reaching; it is socially
injurious. The wealthy or power injure other people knowingly, to establish
their power and status.
That is what Aristophanes meant when his
characters say that wealth is not like bananas or lentil soup. Wealth has no
object but itself. Wealth is status — and also political control. The creditor’s
wealth is the debtor’s liability. The key to its dynamic is not production and
consumption, but assets and liabilities — the economy’s balance sheet. Wealth
and status in the sense of who/whom. It seeks to increase without limit, and
Socrates and Aristotle found the major example to be creditors charging interest
for lending "barren" money. Interest had to be paid out of the debtor’s own
product, income or finally, forfeiture of property; creditors did not provide
means of making interest to pay off the loan.
This is the opposite of Austrian School
theories that interest is a bargain to share the gains to be made from the loan
"fairly" between creditor and debtor. It also is the opposite of neoclassical
price theory. The economics taught in universities today is based on a price
theory that does not even touch on this point. The liberty that oligarchs claim
is the right to indebt the rest of society and then demand full payment or
forfeiture of the debtor’s collateral. This leads to massive expropriations, as
did the Junk Mortgage foreclosures after 2008 when President Obama failed to
write down debts to realistic market values for real estate financed on loans
far beyond the buyer’s ability to pay. The result was 10 million
foreclosures.
Yet today’s mainstream economics treats the
normal tendency to polarize between creditors and debtors, the wealthy and the
have-nots, as an anomaly. It has been the norm for the last five thousand years,
but economics sidesteps actual empirical history as if it is an anomaly in the
fictional parallel universe created by the mainstream’s unrealistic assumptions.
Instead of being a science, such economics is science fiction.It trains students
in cognitive dissonance that distracts them from understanding Classical
Antiquity and the driving dynamics of Western civilization.
JS:This gets us back to the question of
whether universities should just be shut down and started up all over
again.
MH:You don’t shut them down, you create a
new group of universities with a different curriculum. The path of least
resistance is to house this more functional curriculum in new institutions.
That’s what America’s Republican and pro-industrial leaders recognized after the
Civil War ended in 1865. They didn’t shut down Harvard and Yale and Princeton
and the Christian free-trade Anglophile colleges. They created state colleges
funded by land grants, such as Cornell in upstate New York, and business schools
such as the Wharton School at the University of Pennsylvania, endowed by industrialists to providing an
economic logic for the state’s steel-making and related industrial
protectionism. The result was an alternative economics to describe how America
should develop as what they saw as a new civilization, free of the vestiges of
Europe’s feudal privileges, absentee ownership and colonialist
mentality.
The Republicans and industrialists saw that
America’s prestige colleges had been founded long before the Civil War,
basically as religious colleges to train the clergy. They taught British free
trade theory, serving the New England commercial and banking interests and
Southern plantation owners. But free trade kept the United States dependent on
England. My book America’s Protectionist Takeoff describes how the American
School of Political Economy, led by Henry Carey and E. Peshine Smith (William
Seward’s law partner), developed an alternative to what was being taught in the
religious colleges.
This led to a new view of the history of
Western civilization and America’s role in fighting against entrenched
privilege. William Draper’s Intellectual Development of Europe, and Andrew Dixon
White’s History of the Warfare of Science with Theologysaw the United States as
breaking free from the feudal aristocracies that were a product of the way in
which antiquity collapsed, economically and culturally.
JS: So business schools were originally
progressive!
MH: Surprising as it may seem, the answer
is Yes, to the extent that they described the global economy as tending to
polarize under free trade and an absence of government protectionism, not to
become more equal. They incorporated technology, energy-use and the
environmental consequences of trade patterns into economic theory, such as soil
depletion resulting from plantation monocultures. Mainstream economics fought
against such analysis because it advocated markets "free" for polluters, "free"
for nations to pursue policies that made them poorer and dependent on foreign
credit.
JS: So this is how the Wharton School’s
first professor of economics, Simon Patten, one of the founders of American
sociology, fits into this anti-rentier tradition! That is such a revelation to
me! They developed an analysis of technology’s effects on the economy, of
monopoly pricing and economic rent as unearned income that increases the cost of
living and cost of production. They explained the benefits of public
infrastructure investment. Today that is called "socialism," but it was
industrial capitalists who took the lead in urging such public investment, so as
to lower their cost of doing business.
MH: The first U.S. business schools in
the late 19thcentury described rentiers as unproductive. That is why today’s
neoliberals are trying to rewrite the history of Institutionalism in a way that
expurgates the Americans who wanted the government to provide public
infrastructure to make America a low-cost economy, undersell England and other
countries, and evolve into the industrial giant it became by the
1920s.
JS: That was Simon Patten’s teaching at
the Wharton School — government-subsidized public infrastructure as the fourth
factor of production.
MH: Yes. America’s ruling political class
tried to make the United States a dominant economy instead of a rentiereconomy
of landlords and financial manipulators.
JS: How did the robber barons fit into
this story?
MH: Not as industrialists or
manufacturers, but as monopolists opposed by the industrial interests. It was
Teddy Roosevelt’s trust-busting and the Republicans that enacted the Sherman
antitrust act. Its spirit was continued by Franklin Roosevelt.
JS:Is today’s economy a second age of
robber barons?
MH: It’s becoming a second Gilded Age. An
abrupt change of direction in economic trends occurred after Ronald Reagan and
Margaret Thatcher were elected in 1979/80. The result has been to invert what
the 19th-century economists understood to be a free market — that is, a market
free from a privileged hereditary class living on unearned income in the form of
land rent, monopoly rent and financial extraction.
JS: I was in my first few years of
college when Thatcher came in in 1979, and when Reagan was elected in 1980. I
asked my economics professors what was going on, but I could not find a single
professor to coherently describe the U-turn that was occurring. It certainly
wasn’t in Paul Samuelson’s textbook that we were given.
MH: There’s little logic for
neoliberalism beyond a faith that short-term greed is the best way to optimize
long-term growth. It is natural for the wealthiest classes to have this faith.
Neoliberalism doesn’t look at the economy as a social system, and it excludes as
"externalities" concerns with the environment, debt dependency and economic
polarization. It only asks how to make a short-term hit-and-run gain, regardless
of whether this is done in a way that has a positive or negative overall social
effect. Realistic economic logic is social in scope, and distinguishes between
earned and unearned income. That is why economists such as Simon Patten and
Thorstein Veblen decided to start afresh and create the discipline of sociology,
to go beyond narrow individualistic economics being taught.
Today’s mathematical economics is based on
circular reasoning that treats all that has happened as having been inevitable.
It is all survival of the fittest, so it seems that there is no alternative.
This policy conclusion is built into economic methodology. If we weren’t the
fittest, we wouldn’t have survived, so by definition (that is, circular
reasoning), any alternative is less than fit.
Regarding the fact that you had to read
Samuelson when you were in college, he was famous for his Factor Price
Equalization Theorem claiming to prove mathematically that everybody and every
nation tends naturally to become more and more equal (if government stands
aside). He denied that the tendency of the global economy is to polarize, not
equalize. The political essence of this equilibrium theory is its claim that
economies tend to settle in a stable balance. In reality they polarize and then
collapse if they do not reverse their polarizing financial and productivity and
wealth dynamics are.
The starting point of economic theorizing
should explain the dynamic that lead economics to polarize and collapse. That is
the lesson of studying antiquity that we have discussed in our earlier talks.
Writers in classical antiquity, like Bronze Age Near Eastern rulers before them
and the Biblical prophets, recognized that a rentier economy tends to destroy
the economy’s productivity and widespread prosperity, and ultimately its
survival. In today’s world the Finance, Insurance,and Real Estate [FIRE] sector
and monopolies are destroying the rest of the economy, using financial wealth to
take over the government and disable its ability to prevent their operating in
corrosive and predatory ways.
JS: Why aren’t more people up in
arms?
MH: They’re only up in arms if they
believe that there is an alternative. As long as the vested interests can
suppress any idea that there is an alternative, that matters don’t have to be
this way, people just get depressed. In our third interview you spoke about
Socrates and the Stoics producing a philosophy of lamentation and resignation.
By his day there seemed no solution except to denounce wealth. When matters got
much worse in the Roman Empire, wealth was abhorred. That became the message of
Christianity.
What is needed is to define the scope of the
alternative that you want. How can the economy grow when households,
business, and government have to pay
more and more of their revenue to the financial sector, which then turns around
and lends its interest and related income out to indebt the economy even more?
The effect is to extract even more income. Rising government debt and tax cuts
for the rentiers lead to the privatization of public infrastructure and natural
monopolies. Higher prices are charged for tolls to pay for public healthcare,
education, roads and other services that were expected to be provided for free a
century ago. Financialized privatization thus creates a high-rent, high-cost
economy — the opposite of industrial capitalism evolving into socialism to
finally free society from rentier income.
JS:Wouldn’t that be based on the
insatiable desire [?πlhst?a, aplêstia] for money and the super-rich
[?π?rπloutoi,hyper-ploutoi] oligarchs in Book 8 of Plato’s Republic? So we get
back to my question: Is the behavior of the super-rich a constant in human
nature?
MH:Money-love [filocrhmat?a,
philochrêmatia] has always been extreme because wealth is addictive. But their
dynamic of credit — other peoples’ debts— increasing at compound interest is
mathematized and the economy is put on automatic pilot to self-destruct. Its
business plan to "create wealth" by making financial gains at somebody else’s
expense, without limit. This kind of financial wealth is a zero-sum activity.
The wealth of the creditor class, the One Percent, is achieved by indebting the
99 Percent.
JS:Why is it a zero-sum
activity?
MH:A zero-sum activity is when one
party’s gain is another’s loss. Instead of income paid to creditors being
reinvested in means of production to help the economy grow, it’s spent on buying
more assets. The most wasteful examples are corporate stock buyback programs and
financial raids. And the largest effect of financialization occurs as loans and
Quantitative Easing simply bid up the price of real estate, stocks, bonds and
other assets. The effect is to put housing and a retirement income further out
of range of people who have to live by working for wages and salaries instead of
living off absentee ownership, interest and financial asset-price
gains.
JS: Why is this being done instead of
investing in the economy to help the population live a better and more
prosperous life?
MH:The tax and regulatory system is set
up to make financial gains or create monopoly privileges. That is quicker and
more certain, especially in an economy shrinking as a result of financialization
and the austerity it imposes. It’s hard to make profits by investing in a
shrinking economy suffering from debt deflation and a squeeze on family budgets
to pay for health care, education and other basic needs.
JS:So it becomes more about extraction.
Let’s come back to Global Climate Change and rising sea levels as a foundation
of American foreign policy.
MH:Since the 19th century, American
policy has been based on the recognition that GDP growth reflects rising energy
use per capita. Rising productivity is almost identical with the curve of energy
use per worker. That was the basic premise of E. Peshine Smith in 1853, and
subsequent writers, whom I describe in America’s Protectionist Takeoff:
1918-1914. The policy conclusion is that if you can control the source of energy
— which remains mainly oil and coal — then you can control global GDP growth.
That is why Dick Cheney invaded Iraq: to grab its oil. It is why Trump announced
his intention to topple Venezuela and take its oil.
If other nations are obliged to buy their
oil from the United States or its companies, then it’s in a monopoly position to
turn off their electricity (like the United States did to Venezuela) and hurt
their economies if they don’t acquiesce in a world system that lets American
financial firms come in and buy out their most productive monopolies and
privatize theirpublic domain. That’s why America’s foreign policy is to
monopolize the world’s oil, gas and coal in order to have a stranglehold on the
rate of growth of other countries by being able to deny them energy. It’s like
denying countries food in order to starve them out. The aim isto exploit Europe,
Asia, Africa and Latin America what Rome exploited its Empire.
JS:Would you be comfortable using words
like evil to describe what’s going on now?
MH: Evil essentially is predatory and
destructive behavior. Socrates said that it ultimately is ignorance, because
nobody would set out intentionally to do it. But in that case, evil would be an
educational system that imposes ignorance and tunnel vision, distracting
attention from understanding how economic society actually works in destructive
ways. On that logic, post-classical neoliberal economics and the Chicago Boys
are evil because their ideology breeds ignorance and leads its believers to act
in ways that are injurious to society, preventing personal fulfillment through
economic growth. Evil is a policy that makes most of society poorer, simply in
order to enrich an increasingly wealth-addictive rentier layer at the top.
Werner Sombart described the bourgeoisie as floating like a globules of fat on
top of a soup.
JS: This is now happening on a path that
follows an exponential extreme. I guess global warming makes it particularly
evil. We’re not simply talking about taking advantage of other people within a
society, we’re talking about destruction of the planet and its
environment.
MH: Economists dismiss this as an
"externality," that is, outside the scope of their models. So these models are
deliberately ignorant. You could say that this makes them evil.
JS: That is what I’ve suspected since we
started the Iraq War in 2003.
MH: America’s military buildup, its
anti-environmental policy and global wars are part of the same symbiotic
strategy. The reason why America will not be part of a real effort to mitigate
global warming is that its policy is still based on grabbing the oil resources
of the Near East, Venezuela, and everywhere else that it can. Also, the oil
industry is the most tax-exempt and politically powerful sector. If it also
happens to be the primary cause of global warming, that is viewed as just
collateral damage to America’s attempt to control the world by controlling the
oil supply. In that sense the environmental impasse is a byproduct of American
imperialism.
JS:What’s hopeful in the United States
right now? What is a possible good outcome?
MH:T he precondition would be for people
to realize that there is an alternative. Starting with wiping out of student
debts, they can realize that the overall debt overhead can be wiped out without
hurting the economy — and indeed, rescuing it from the financial rentier class
inasmuch as all debts on the liabilities side of the balance sheet have their
counterpart on the asset side as the savings of today’s financial oligarchy,
which is doing to the U.S. economy what Rome’s Senate did to the ancient
world.
JS: How can people proceed from
here?
MH: Understanding must come first. Once
you have to have a sense of history, you realize that there is an alternative.
You also see what happens when a creditor oligarchy gets strong enough to
prevent any public power from writing down debts and to prevent attempts to tax
it.
You have to do to America today what the
Republicans did after the Civil War: You have to have a new university
curriculum dealing with economic history, the history of economic thought and
the real world’s long-term development.
JS: And what would be the premise for
such economic history?
MH:T he starting point is to realize that
civilization began in the ancient Near East, and made a turn to oppose a strong
public regulatory sector in Classical Greece and Rome. The long-term tension is
the eternal fight by the oligarchy of creditors and large land owners to reduce
the rest of society to serfdom, and to oppose strong rulers empowered to act in
the economy’s long-term interest by creating checks against this
polarization.
JS: So how much longer does this go on —
for months, for years, for decades?
MH: It always goes on longer than you
think it will. Inertia has a great elastic self-reinforcing power. Polarization
will widen until people believe that there is an alternative and decide to fight
for it. Two things are required for this to happen: First, a large proportion of
people need to see that the economy is impoverishing them, and that the existing
picture of what is happening is misleading. Instead of wealth trickling down, it
is defying gravity and sucking income up from the base of the economic pyramid.
People are having to work harder just to stay in place, until their life style
breaks down.
Second, people must realize that it doesn’t
have to be this way. There isan alternative
JS: Right now most people think that
government regulation and progressive taxation will make things worse, and that
the wealthy are job creators, not job destroyers. They think that the system
needs to be bolstered, not replaced, because the alternative is "socialism" —
that is, what the Soviets did, not what Franklin Roosevelt was doing. But today
bailing out the banks and giving subsidies to new employers is said to be for
our own good.
MH: That’s what the Romans told their
provinces. Everything they did was always to preserve "good order," meaning open
opportunities for their own wealth grabbing. They never said they were out to
destroy and loot other societies. Madeline Albright followed this rhetorical
pattern in describing as being, like the Romans and France’s brutal mission
civilisatrice, a program to uplift the world free-market efficiency. For
performing this service, the imperial power takes all the money that its
colonies, provinces and allies can generate. That’s why the U.S. meddles in
foreign politics, as we have just seen in Ukraine, Libya and Syria.
JS: You’ve described the greatest
meddling as distorting the narrative of history to depict creditor and rentier
drives toward oligarchy as being democratic and helping to raise living
standards and culture. Your books show just the opposite.
MH: Thank you.
No comments:
Post a Comment
Note: Only a member of this blog may post a comment.