Richard A. Werner: solutions to the European & Japanese internal debt
crises
(1) Debt-Deflation Depression the result of Deregulation,
misallocation
of Capital - London Banker
(2) Richard A. Werner: solutions
to the European & Japanese internal
debt crises
(3) ECB keeping the
threat of financial Armageddon alive, to coerce
Europe into a deeper
union
(1) Debt-Deflation Depression the result of Deregulation,
misallocation
of Capital - London Banker
http://londonbanker.blogspot.com.au/2008/07/fishers-debt-deflation-theory-of-great.html
Fisher's
Debt-Deflation Theory of Great Depressions, and a possible
revision
London Banker Blogsite
Friday 1 August
2008
“Panics do not destroy capital; they merely reveal the extent to
which
it has been destroyed by its betrayal into hopelessly unproductive
works.”
- Mr John Mills, Article read before the Manchester Statistical
Society,
December 11, 1867, on Credit Cycles and the Origin of Commercial
Panics
as quoted in Financial crises and periods of industrial and
commercial
depression, Burton, T. E. (1931, first published 1902). New York
and
London: D. Appleton & Co
I have been both a central banker
and a market regulator. I now find
myself questioning whether my early
career, largely devoted to
liberalising and deregulating banking financial
markets, was misguided.
In short, I wonder whether I contributed - along
with a countless others
in regulation, banking, academia and politics - to a
great misallocation
of capital, distortion of markets and the impairment of
the real
economy. We permitted the banks to betray capital into “hopelessly
unproductive works”, promoting their efforts with monetary laxity,
regulatory forbearance and government tax incentives that marginalised
investment in “productive works”. We permitted markets to become so
fragmented by off-exchange trading and derivatives that they no longer
perform the economically critical functions of capital/resource
allocation and price discovery efficiently or transparently. The results
have been serial bubbles - debt-financed speculative frenzy in real
estate, investments and commodities.
Since August of 2007 we have
been seeing a steady constriction of credit
markets, starting with subprime
mortgage back securities, spreading to
commercial paper and then to
interbank credit and then to bond markets
and then to securities generally.
While the problem is usually expressed
as one of confidence, a more honest
conclusion is that credit extended
in the past has been employed
unproductively and so will not be repaid
according to the original terms. In
other words, capital has been
betrayed into unproductive works.
The
credit crunch today is not destroying capital but recognising that
capital
was destroyed by misallocation in the years of irrational
exuberance. If
that is so, then we are entering a spiral of debt
deflation that will play
out slowly for years to come. To understand how
that works, we turn to
Professor Irving Fisher of Yale.
Like me, Professor Fisher lived to
question his earlier convictions and
pursuits, learning by dear experience
the lessons of financial instability.
Professor Fisher was an early
mathematical economist, specialising in
monetary and financial economics.
Fisher’s contributions to the field of
economics included the equation of
exchange, the distinction between
real and nominal interest rates, and an
early analysis of intertemporal
allocation. As his status grew, he became an
icon for popularising 1920s
fads for investment, healthy living and social
engineering, including
Prohibition and eugenics.
He is less famous
for all of this today than for his one statement in
September 1929 that
“stock prices had reached a permanently high
plateau”. He subsequently lost
a personal fortune of between $6 and $10
million in the crash. As J.K.
Galbraith remarked, “This was a sizable
sum, even for an economics
professor.” Fisher’s investment bank failed
in the bear market, losing the
fortunes of investors and his public
reputation.
Professor Fisher
made his “permanently high plateau” remark in an
environment very similar to
that prevailing in the summer of 2007.
Currencies had been competitively
devalued in all the major nations as
each sought to gain or defend export
market share. The devaluation
stoked asset bubbles as easy credit led to
more and more speculative
investments, including a boom in globalisation as
investors bought bonds
from abroad to gain higher yields. Then, as now, many
speculators on
Wall Street had unshakeable faith in the Federal Reserve’s
ability to
keep the party going.
After the crash and financial ruin,
Professor Fisher turned his
considerable talents to determining the
underlying mechanisms of the
crash. His Debt-Deflation Theory of Great
Depressions (1933) was
powerful and resonant, although largely neglected by
officialdom, Wall
Street and academia alike. Fisher’s theory raised too many
uncomfortable
questions about the roles played by the Federal Reserve, Wall
Street and
Washington in propagating the conditions for credit excess and
the debt
deflation that followed.
The whole paper is worth reading
carefully, but I’ll extract here some
choice quotes which give a flavour of
the whole. Prefacing his theory,
Fisher first discusses instability around
equilibrium and the influence
of ‘forced’ cycles (like seasons) and ‘free’
cycles (self-generating
like waves). Unlike the Chicago School, Fisher says
bluntly that “exact
equilibrium thus sought is seldom reached and never long
maintained. New
disturbances are, humanly speaking, sure to occur, so that,
in actual
fact, any variable is almost always above or below ideal
equilibrium.”
He bluntly asserts:
“Theoretically there may be — in
fact, at most times there must be —
over- or under-production, over- or
under-consumption, over- or
under-spending, over- or under-saving, over- or
under-investment, and
over or under everything else. It is as absurd to
assume that, for any
long period of time, the variables in the economic
organization, or any
part of them, will “stay put,” in perfect equilibrium,
as to assume that
the Atlantic Ocean can ever be without a
wave.”
While disturbances will cause oscillations which lead to
recessions, he
suggests:
"[I]n the great booms and depressions, each
of the above-named factors
has played a subordinate role as compared with
two dominant factors,
namely over-indebtedness to start with and deflation
following soon
after; also that where any of the other factors do become
conspicuous,
they are often merely effects or symptoms of these
two.”
This is the critical argument of the paper. Viewed from this
perspective
we may see USA and UK decades of under-production,
over-consumption,
over-spending and under-investment as all tending to a
greater imbalance
in debt which may, if combined with oscillations induced
by
disturbances, take the US and UK economies beyond the point where they
could right themselves into a deflationary spiral.
Fisher outlines
how just 9 factors interacting with one another under
conditions of debt and
deflation create the mechanics of boom to bust
for a Great
Depression:
Assuming, accordingly, that, at some point of time, a state
of
over-indebtedness exists, this will tend to lead to liquidation, through
the alarm either of debtors or creditors or both. Then we may deduce the
following chain of consequences in nine links: (1) Debt liquidation
leads to distress selling and to (2) Contraction of deposit currency, as
bank loans are paid off, and to a slowing down of velocity of
circulation. This contraction of deposits and of their velocity,
precipitated by distress selling, causes (3) A fall in the level of
prices, in other words, a swelling of the dollar. Assuming, as above
stated, that this fall of prices is not interfered with by reflation or
otherwise, there must be (4) A still greater fall in the net worths of
business, precipitating bankruptcies and (5) A like fall in profits,
which in a “capitalistic,” that is, a private-profit society, leads the
concerns which are running at a loss to make (6) A reduction in output,
in trade and in employment of labor. These losses, bankruptcies and
unemployment, lead to (7) Hoarding and slowing down still more the
velocity of circulation.
The above eight changes cause (9)
Complicated disturbances in the rates
of interest, in particular, a fall in
the nominal, or money, rates and a
rise in the real, or commodity, rates of
interest.
Evidently debt and deflation go far toward explaining a great
mass of
phenomena in a very simple logical way.
Hyman Minsky and
James Tobin credited Fisher’s Debt-Deflation Theory as
a crucial precursor
of their theories of macroeconomic financial
instability.
Fisher
explicitly ties loose money to over-indebtedness, fuelling
speculation and
asset bubbles:
Easy money is the great cause of over-borrowing. When an
investor thinks
he can make over 100 per cent per annum by borrowing at 6
per cent, he
will be tempted to borrow, and to invest or speculate with the
borrowed
money. This was a prime cause leading to the over-indebtedness of
1929.
Inventions and technological improvements created wonderful investment
opportunities, and so caused big debts. * * *
The public psychology
of going into debt for gain passes through several
more or less distinct
phases: (a) the lure of big prospective dividends
or gains in income in the
remote future; (b) the hope of selling at a
profit, and realising a capital
gain in the immediate future; (c) the
vogue of reckless promotions, taking
advantage of the habituation of the
public to great expectations; (d) the
development of downright fraud,
imposing on a public which had grown
credulous and gullible.
Fisher then sums up his theory of debt, deflation
and instability in one
paragraph:
In summary, we find that: (1)
economic changes include steady trends and
unsteady occasional disturbances
which act as starters for cyclical
oscillations of innumerable kinds; (2)
among the many occasional
disturbances, are new opportunities to invest,
especially because of new
inventions; (3) these, with other causes,
sometimes conspire to lead to
a great volume of over-indebtedness; (4) this
in turn, leads to attempts
to liquidate; (5) these, in turn, lead (unless
counteracted by
reflation) to falling prices or a swelling dollar; (6) the
dollar may
swell faster than the number of dollars owed shrinks; (7) in that
case,
liquidation does not really liquidate but actually aggravates the
debts,
and the depression grows worse instead of better, as indicated by all
nine factors; (8) the ways out are either laissez faire (bankruptcy) or
scientific medication (reflation), and reflation might just as well have
been applied in the first place.
The lender of last resort function
of central banks and government
support of the financial system through GSEs
and fiscal measures are the
modern mechanisms of reflation. Like Keynes, I
suspect that Fisher saw
reflation as a limited and temporary intervention
rather than a long
term sustained policy of credit expansion a la
Greenspan/Bernanke.
I’m seriously worried that reflationary practice by
Washington and the
Fed in response to every market hiccup in recent decades
was storing up
a bigger debt deflation problem for the future. This very
scary chart
(click through to view) gives a measure of the threat in
comparing
Depression era total debt to GDP to today’s much higher debt to
GDP.
Certainly Washington and the Fed have been very enthusiastic and
innovative in “reflating” the debt-sensitive financial, real estate,
automotive and consumer sectors for the past many years. I’m tempted to
coin a new noun for reflation enthusiasm: refllatio?
Had Fisher
observed the Greenspan/Bernanke Fed in action, he might have
updated his
theory with a revision. At some point, capital betrayed into
unproductive
works has to either be repaid or written off. If either is
inhibited by
reflation or regulatory forbearance, then a cost is imposed
on productive
works, whether through inflation, higher interest,
diversion of consumption,
or taxation to socialise losses. Over time
that cost ultimately hollows out
the real productive economy leaving
only bubble assets standing. Without a
productive foundation, as
reflation and forbearance reach their limits,
those bubble assets must
deflate.
Fisher’s debt deflation theory was
little recognised in his lifetime,
probably because he was right in drawing
attention to the systemic
failures that precipitated the crash. Speaking
truth to power isn’t a
ticket to popularity today either
London
Banker has been a central banker and securities markets regulator
during a
varied and interesting career in global financial markets.
http://londonbanker.blogspot.com.au/2012/05/heads-i-win-tails-you-lose.html
TUESDAY,
29 MAY 2012
"Heads I win, tails you lose."
I was at a private
lunch in the City some 15 years ago discussing
whether hedge fund
investments should be considered a new and distinct
asset class. A very
prominent hedge fund trader was asked his opinion.
Surprisingly, he said
that hedge funds were less a new method for
investment, than a new method
for higher remuneration. The appeal of
hedge funds was in the outsize fees
rewarding the fund managers rather
than any superior returns for
investors.
I was reminded of that lunch again this morning by two pieces
in my
inbox. The first referenced a paper from the Bank of England
estimating
the public subsidy of the UK's largest banks at more than £220
billion
during the past couple years. These banks secure a funding premium
in
wholesale and deposit markets from the implicit state guarantee of
obligations attaching to their too big to fail status. The subsidy
distorts competition and risk taking, storing up even more future draws
on beleaguered taxpayers. The second was a blogpost summarising recent
comments of a Bank of England executive to the effect that all the cost
savings generated by technology advances and automation in the banking
sector had been paid away in increased bonuses and remuneration. IT
efficiency gains fund bonus payments. The financial sector's appetite
for technology investment is not driven by a desire to provide more
efficient services, but to secure ever larger remuneration packages. In
fact, rapid financial innovation and technology transformation has led
to less efficient intermediation if evaluated on a cost
basis.
Regulation has had a pernicious effect in driving technology and
complexity. As Chris Skinner observes,
Put another way, in the first
iteration of the Basel Accord there were
seven risk metrics requiring seven
calculations; by the time we get
around to implementing Basel III, over
200,000 risk categories will
require over 200 million calculations.At some
point policy makers will
need to turn their efforts from reinforcing and
bailing out the bankers
who use any and every opportunity to take public
support as private
bonuses and instead evaluate much simpler, lower cost
models of
financial intermediation likely to yield domestic investment in
domestic
businesses and assets.
I can almost hear the shouts of
"socialist" from the usual defenders of
banks and markets. I am not
advocating state nationalistion of banks,
but state withdrawal of explicit
and implicit bank subsidies.
It is a conservative principle that the
state should intervene when
markets fail. If the banking system has failed
(and it has) and requires
a taxpayer subsidy to continue to operate (which
it does), then
conservative principles dictate that the state must intervene
to secure
a resolution in the public interest. More of the same is not a
conservative policy, but social welfare for bankers.
We currently
have a system of excess regulatory complexity, hidden
market distortions and
public subsidies. Moving away from the status quo
requires state action to
identify and reduce subsidy through promotion
of business models that are
simpler, more transparent and more directly
aimed at securing public
benefit.
Posted by London Banker at 07:23
(2) Richard A.
Werner: solutions to the European & Japanese internal
debt
crises
http://eprints.soton.ac.uk/341650/
pdf
version:
http://eprints.soton.ac.uk/341650/1/CBFSD_2%2D12_Werner_Euro_Solution_31_Jul_2012.pdf
Richard
A. Werner (2012), How to End the European Crisis, University of
Southampton,
CBFSD Policy Discussion Paper 2-12 | Centre for Banking,
Finance and
Sustainable Development University of Southampton
{p. 1} How to End the
European Crisis – at no further cost and without
the need for political
changes
by Richard A. Werner, D.Phil. (Oxon)
Professor of
International Banking
Centre for Banking, Finance and Sustainable
Development
University of Southampton
31 July
2012
Content:
Executive Summary: True Quantitative Easing p.
2
1. How to solve the bad-debt problem in the banking system most
efficiently and cost-effectively. p. 3
2. Enhanced Debt Management:
How to solve the sovereign funding problem
in the bond markets – and at the
same time stimulate domestic demand p. 9
Further Reading p. 11
{p.
2} Executive Summary
There is a solution to the twin problem of large
non-performing loans in
the banking systems and the funding crisis for
sovereign borrowers that
is affecting especially Spain, Portugal, Ireland,
Cyprus, Greece, but to
some extent also Italy and other
countries.
The needed policies constitute 'true quantitative easing': I
argued in
1994 and 1995 in Japan that there was no need for a recession in
Japan
due to the bad debt problems in the banking system. Necessary and
sufficient condition for a recovery is an expansion in credit creation –
which I called 'quantitative easing', an expression that was later used
by central banks to refer to the type of traditional monetarist policy
(bank reserve expansion) that I had warned would fail.
True
quantitative easing can be achieved quickly and without extra costs
in a
two-part process as follows:
1. The central bank purchases all actual and
likely non-performing
assets from the banks at face value (book value) and
transfers them to
its balance sheet. In the case of non-securitised loans,
if needed a law
should be passed to allow compulsory purchase by and
reassignment to the
central bank.
2. The government stops the
issuance of government bonds. Instead, it
funds any future borrowing
requirement (including all scheduled 'roll-
overs' of bonds) by entering
into loan contracts with the domestic
banks, borrowing at the much lower
prime rate.
Ideally, these two measures are combined, and part and parcel
of a
larger policy package. For a fuller list of measures, see our CBFSD
Discussion Paper No. 1-12.1
But they can also be implemented
separately, so if ECB and national
central bank support cannot be gained for
measure 1, national
governments can end the negative vicious cycle and end
their sovereign
debt problems by going ahead on their own with part
2.
1 Richard A. Werner (2012), The Euro-Crisis: A to-do list for the ECB,
University of Southampton Centre for Banking, Finance and Sustainable
Development, CBFSD Policy Discussion Paper No. 1-12.
{p. 3} How to
End the European Financial Crisis – at no further cost and
without the need
for political changes
There is a solution to the twin problem of large
non-performing loans in
the banking systems and the funding crisis for
sovereign borrowers that
is affecting especially Spain, Portugal, Ireland,
Cyprus, Greece, but to
some extent also Italy and other
countries.
The needed policies constitute 'true quantitative easing': I
argued in
1994 and 1995 in Japan that there was no need for a recession in
Japan
due to the bad debt problems in the banking system. According to the
Quantity Theory of Credit, which I had introduced in 1991, and which
enabled me to predict the Japanese crisis and recession, I also pointed
out that it was avoidable if the right policies were taken:
2
Necessary and sufficient condition for a recovery is an expansion in
credit creation – which I called 'quantitative easing', an expression
that was later used by central banks to refer to the type of traditional
monetarist policy (bank reserve expansion) that I had warned would fail.
3
Sadly, the Japanese government did not adopt the recommended policies.
Neither did the Japanese central bank, which insisted on continuing to
rely on interest rate policies or, later, bank reserve expansion
policies (which it misleadingly called 'quantitative easing') – policies
I had warned would fail.
I believe the empirical record speaks for
itself: Japan remains mired in
its twenty- year recession, soon to commence
its third decade, while
national debt has topped 200% of
GDP.
Fortunately for Europe, we now have the hindsight of the Japanese
experience and there is even less reason why one should adopt failed and
hugely costly policies, and turn down effective and costless
policies.
In the following sections we discuss the two main pillars of
the
policies I am recommending. For a full set of policies, please refer to
CBFSD Discussion Paper No. 1-12. 4
2 Richard A. Werner (1992). A
Quantity Theory of Credit, University of
Oxford, Institute of Economics and
Statistics, mimeo. See also Richard
A. Werner (1997), Towards a New Monetary
Paradigm: A Quantity Theorem of
Disaggregated Credit, with Evidence from
Japan, Kredit und Kapital, 30,
2, pp. 276-309. Available at http://eprints.soton.ac.uk/36569/
3
Richard A. Werner (1995). How to create a recovery through
'Quantitative
Monetary Easing'. The Nihon Keizai Shinbun (Nikkei), 2
September 1995
(morning edition), p.26 (in Japanese). English
Translation available at http://eprints.soton.ac.uk/340476/
. For
further details of the policies proposed, see Richard A. Werner
(1998),
Minkanginkoukarano kariire de keikitaisaku wo okonaeba issekinichou,
Economist (Japan), 14 Jul., 1998 and Richard A. Werner (2002), 'How to
Get Growth in Japan', Central Banking, vol. XIII, no. 2, November 2002,
pp. 48-54 4 Richard A. Werner (2012), The Euro-Crisis: A to-do list for
the ECB, University of Southampton Centre for Banking, Finance and
Sustainable Development, CBFSD Policy Discussion Paper No. 1-12.
{p.
4} 1. How to solve the bad-debt problem in the banking system most
efficiently and cost-effectively.
The current approach adopted by the
European and IMF leadership of how
to handle large and growing bad debts in
the banking system, for
instance in Spain or Greece, is to ask the affected
states to borrow
even more money. This is further use of public i.e. tax
money (either
national, European or international), which is then used to
recapitalise
banks and help them write off bad debts. This is a very
expensive method
and adds to the already major problem of excessive
sovereign debt.
Economics tells us that a zero-cost alternative is
available, and has
indeed been adopted successfully in the past.
We
must remember that the problem of insolvent banks, due to bad debts,
is
fundamentally a standard accounting problem: the balance sheet of
banks
shows a hole on the asset side: Instead of the original value of
assets of,
say, 100, the market value of the assets has dropped. This
quickly produces
a bust banking system, since already a fall in asset
values by ten percent
means that most banks would have used up all
equity and thus would be
bankrupt. Due to the nonperforming loans banks
have also become highly
risk-averse and unwilling to grant new loans. As
a result, bank credit
growth has slowed to zero or negative in many
European countries. This is
why domestic demand will stay weak in Spain,
Ireland, Italy, Greece – if
nothing is done to kick-start bank credit
growth. 5
How can this
accounting problem of non-performing assets be solved? If
only we could use
an eraser, rub out the nonperforming asset entries in
the accounts, and
write in a market value of 100 again!
Actually, this can be done without
suspending any accounting conventions
by one particular player: the central
bank. Spain and Italy have
national central banks that have, according to
the ECB, some discretion
over their asset purchases.
My proposal is
for the national central banks to purchase all
nonperforming assets (actual,
not official, since the official figures
understate the scale of NPLs) from
the banks at face value (100).
Immediately the health of the banking sector
would be fully restored.
Let's assume the market value of the NPLs is 20,
but the central bank
has bought them for 100. While we have solved the
problem for the banks,
have we not just shifted the problem onto the central
bank balance
sheet? In other words, does the central bank not now face
insolvency,
with a loss of 80 on its purchases of assets for a face value of
100
although they only have a market value of 20?
No, we have not
just shifted the problem, we have solved it – and at
zero cost to the tax
payer at that. Firstly, central banks do not need
to mark to market.
Secondly, the central bank could in reality not
possibly make a loss of 80
on this transaction. Instead, it makes a
profit of 20. The reason is that
the central bank has zero funding costs
for this operation, yet obtains
something worth 20 – a gain, then, not a
loss.
5 The Quantity Theory
of Credit tells us that a necessary and sufficient
condition for an economic
recovery is an increase in credit creation
used for GDP
transactions.
{p. 5} If it's so simple and costless, why has no central
bank done this
before? Actually, three major central banks have done it
before: the
Bank of England, the Bank of Japan and, most recently, the US
Federal
Reserve. The result: the operations were a complete success, as was
to
be expected. No inflation resulted. The currency did not weaken. Despite
massive non-performing assets wiping out the solvency and equity of the
banking sector, the banks' health was quickly restored. In the UK and
Japanese case, bank credit started to recover quickly, so that there was
virtually no recession at all as a result.
Details: The UK
Case
It is August 1914. Britain has just declared war on Germany and its
allies (the Austro- Hungarian empire and the Ottoman Empire). However, a
substantial proportion of international financial transactions between
these Empires and the rest of the world were transacted through London,
so that upon the declaration of war, major parts of British banks'
assets consisted of securities and loans that could not be called and
were, due to the state of war, legally in default. The British banking
system was bust – and in a much worse situation than in 2007 or 2008
when most recently British banks became insolvent.
But since the Bank
of England had no interest in creating a banking
crisis and credit crunch
recession, it simply bought the non-performing
assets from the banks. There
was no credit crunch, and no recession.
Problem solved. At zero cost to the
tax payer.
Details: The Japanese Case
In August 1945 the balance
sheet of Japanese banks was far worse than
their balance sheet in the 1990s
or 2000s: non-performing assets
amounted to virtually 100% of assets (since
assets consisted mainly of
forced loans to munitions companies and forced
purchases of war bonds).
The firms were bankrupt. The government defaulted
on the war bonds.
But in 1945 the Bank of Japan had no interest in
creating a banking
crisis and a credit crunch recession. Instead it wanted
to ensure that
bank credit would flow again, delivering economic growth. So
the Bank of
Japan bought the non-performing assets from the banks – not at
market
value (close to zero), but significantly above market value. The
banks
were healed again. Together with some other measures, bank credit
growth
recovered and so did the economy. 6
Details: The US
Case
The Federal Reserve has been the central bank most active in
implementing this policy in recent decades. It purchased several
trillion dollars worth of non- performing assets from the US banking and
financial institutions. This drastically improved their balance sheets
and avoided default of many banks.
6 For more details on the Japanese
case, see Werner, Richard A. (2009).
Financial crises in Japan during the
20th century. Bankhistorisches
Archiv, 47, 98-123, available at
http://eprints.soton.ac.uk/186635/1/Werner_Bankhistor_Archiv_2009_postfinal.pdf
{p.
6} How could the Federal Reserve have come up with this idea?
Chairman Ben
Bernanke was an active participant in the wide-ranging and
intense policy
debates in the 1990s in Japan which I was also active in,
and during which
time I first proposed these and related policies under
the label of
'quantitative easing'. He had been one of the more
open-minded voices and
often joined my criticism of the Bank of Japan
and calls for more drastic
central bank action. He may also have read my
2001 book Princes of the Yen,
an illegal, Bank of Japan-translated
English version of which circulated
widely in Washington as early as
2001. The US State Department at the time
also took an interest in my work.
In the original version of Princes of
the Yen, I warn of how Alan
Greenspan was creating a massive boom-bust cycle
that will burst,
causing financial dislocation in the US. 7 In the English
Version of
Princes of the Yen I also warn of a major boom- bust cycle in
Europe,
with the European asset bubbles caused by an excessively powerful
and
unaccountable ECB. 8
In my 2005 book I again warned of the next
bout of massive banking
crises, especially in
Europe.
Objections
The immediate objection to this proposal is
usually that it will produce
inflation. However, this cannot happen:
inflation can only come about,
when those who are able to create money (the
central bank and the banks,
collectively forming the banking system) inject
money into the rest of
the economy (which is not able to create money). The
asset purchases by
the central bank merely constitute transactions between
the central bank
and the banks, re-ordering matters within the banking
system. As a
result, not a single dollar is injected into the non-banking
sector.
Hence there could not possibly be inflation.
This prediction
has been borne out by the facts. When the Fed multiplied
its balance sheet
size through its non-performing asset purchases, many
observers thought this
would create inflation and sharply weaken the
dollar. Neither happened, for
the same reason: no new money was injected
into the non-banking economy. So
all kudos to Ben for his courage.
Incidentally, having averted a melt-down
Dr. Bernanke now needs to
follow part 2 of my advice (see below), otherwise
he could still face a
long recession.
7 Excerpts from Chapter 19 of
the Japanese original of Princes of the
Yen: "When the US stock market
collapses and overextended banks veer on
the brink of bankruptcy, individual
savers will not lose their
livelihood, as they did in the 1920s. America now
has a deposit
insurance system. The problem is, however, that due to
financial
deregulation, the money is not in the bank anymore. Over the past
25
years, a dramatic shift of savings has taken place, from bank deposits
to the equity market. Whether directly or via mutual funds, up to 50% of
individual savings are now invested in the stock market. And there is no
insurance against capital losses in the stock market yet.” … "Alan
Greenspan knows that the economic dislocation that will follow his
bubble will let previous post- war economic crises pale by comparison.
Individual savers will lose their money. In the words of Alan Greenspan
(1967): "The financial policy of the welfare state requires that there
be no way for the owners of wealth to protect themselves.” Large losses
will be incurred by most Americans, when the Fed changes its policy and
sharply and consistently reduces credit creation, as it ultimately will.
A Great Depression is possible. Of course, it could be avoided by the
right policies.” Richard A. Werner (2001). En no Shihaisha (Princes of
the Yen), Tokyo: Soshisha
8 Richard A. Werner (2003), Princes of the
Yen, Japan's Central Bankers
and the Structural Transformation of the
Economy, M. E. Sharpe – with
the last chapter on Europe and what I saw was
the likelihood of a
massive boom-bust cycle created by a too-independent
ECB. Richard A.
Werner (2005), New Paradigm in Macroeconomics, Palgrave
Macmillan
{p. 7} Another objection was voiced to me by Jörg Asmussen,
executive
director of the ECB, on 18 June 2012, as a fellow-panellist during
a
public debate in Berlin. Obviously not having heard this proposal
before, and pushed by me and the audience to respond to my proposal and
the question why governments prefer to waste billions of tax money, when
the banks could be capitalised at zero new costs to the tax payer – the
highest ranking German official at the ECB responded by saying that such
a solution could not exist, 'because there is no free lunch'.
Admittedly, given the unimpressive set of policies we have been
presented with over the past two years, this almost sounds too good to
be true.
I was not given the chance to retort, and my response would
have been:
make no mistake, this is no free lunch. We have experienced a
massive
multi-year credit expansion in the banking systems in Ireland,
Portugal,
Spain and Greece, which have produced asset bubbles and vast
resource
misallocations, including millions of bankruptcies and home
repossessions. These are real and high costs to society. The collapse
that followed has greatly burdened government budgets and fiscal
expenditure on the non-banking part of the economy, such as welfare,
health and education, have been drastically cut. Unemployment has risen
to record levels in many periphery countries. These are massive real
costs – so I don't see how we can talk about a 'free lunch'. And
precisely because this crisis has been so immensely costly to society it
makes no sense whatsoever to further add to these costs through
misguided banking bail-out policies.
Finally, one often hears the
objection that if we bail out the banks in
this way, won't they just get
onto the same old tricks very soon – the
moral hazard argument. Well, we are
bailing out the banks – using tax
money. And the moral hazard argument says
that we should not use tax
money, for it was not the tax payers that have
been responsible for the
bad debts. The principle is that who messes up
should own up. So we do
need to ask the question of just who is responsible
for the banking
crises that has befallen Ireland, Spain in particular, as
well as
Portugal and Greece.
So who is responsible for the 25%, 30%
or even 40% bank credit growth
that was recorded for months on end, until
about 2007, in countries such
as Ireland, Portugal, Spain and Greece? Whose
job is it to monitor and
rein in bank credit expansion? It is the job of the
European Central
Bank. Did the ECB have the powers and tools available to
prevent this?
It certainly did. The most powerful and independent central
bank in the
world has complete freedom to choose its policy instruments and
policy
targets. It chose to allow a vast credit bubble, which must result –
as
these bubbles always do – in massive non-performing loans in the banking
systems. So since the ECB has been responsible, it should also pay
up.
Political Obstacles
This policy is only possible with the
cooperation of the central bank.
So if governments have given up control or
influence over central banks,
as is the case in the European Union, the
central bank has to be
convinced by rational economic argument of the
superiority of this
measure in order to adopt it voluntarily. The reader is
asked to
contribute to this up-hill battle by forwarding this report to
anyone in
senior positions in society, business, academia, think tanks,
parties,
bureaucracies or the political leadership.
Since
independence is a great privilege that imposes the moral
responsibility on
central banks to be transparent and accountable for
their policies, the ECB
needs to explain to us why it is not inclined to
adopt such a policy. If
national central banks
{p. 8} cannot be persuaded to voluntarily use
their national discretion
to implement it, they should be asked to explain
in great detail why
they oppose such a policy. My feeling is that the ECB
leadership is
aware of the possibility of such a policy, but has (too early,
in my
view) committed itself to a different course of action. Senior ECB
officials have squarely stated that they favour the adoption of a
banking union, Eurobonds, fiscal union, a European Finance Ministry and
even the creation of a United States of Europe. Quite a few ECB leaders
were personally connected to the people who co-authored the Maastricht
Treaty of 1991, or were, as is the case with Jean-Claude Trichet,
outright co-authors.
Their argument has so far been justified by the
claim that, in
Thatcherite manner, 'there is no alternative'. This is why I
want to
state categorically that there is an alternative that is
economically
superior, will maintain the euro and does not require any of
these
European centralisation measures.
Bloomberg has even raised the
possibility that the ECB may cherish the
current ongoing slow-motion type of
crisis, as it might consider it the
best opportunity to convince national
politicians and the general public
to support the goal of the creation of a
United States of Europe.
"Central bank officials may be hoping that by
keeping the threat of
financial Armageddon alive, they can coerce the
region's people and
governments into moving toward the deeper union that the
euro's creators
envisioned." 9
Since this would suggest an extreme
degree of cynicism on behalf of the
ECB, this interpretation is hard to
swallow for those inexperienced in
central banking matters. In any case, the
ECB needs to be asked to
explain why it is opposed to any bank bailouts that
do not require
further tax money nor a banking nor fiscal union. My baseline
scenario
is that the ECB is likely to oppose this proposal, although we do
look
forward to hearing the details of any counter-arguments – as they will
be easily disproven.
We thus suggest as the main thrust of
national-level government policy
to opt immediately for Part 2 of our
proposal. While that does not get
rid of the bad debts in the banking system
in one stroke at zero
additional cost, as Part 1 does, it will achieve the
same ultimate goal,
and likely do so very quickly: namely to boost domestic
demand,
especially in affected countries such as Ireland, Portugal, Spain,
Italy
and Greece.
9 Bloomberg, Editorial, 25 October 2011, accessed
at
http://www.bloomberg.com/news/print/2011-10-25/euro-s-self-styled-saviors-could-be-its-greatest-enemies-view.html
Their argument follows mine in Princes of the Yen, 2003.
{p. 9} 2.
Enhanced Debt-Management: How to solve the sovereign funding
problem in the
bond markets – and at the same time stimulate domestic demand
Today (24
July 2012) Spain paid a new post-euro record high interest
rate on its newly
issued government bonds. Borrowing rates in the bond
market have risen to
unsustainable levels. This was also the problem in
Greece, Ireland and
Portugal, and could also easily become a problem for
Italy.
Observers
are well aware of the negative feedback loops: the troubled
banking systems,
when dealt with through government money and not
central bank money, worsen
the fiscal situation of the government
drastically. It is expensive to bail
out a banking system. Ireland
boasted a strong fiscal position, until its
government offered to bail
out the banking system. It subsequently teetered
on insolvency and
called in IMF (and European) funding.
As
speculators know when bonds mature and large tranches need to be
refinanced,
they can usually earn money by shorting bonds around these
dates, hence
pushing up interest rates. This makes it a self-fulfilling
bet, since higher
rates worsen the fiscal position of the government.
A further negative
feedback loop occurs via the credit rating agencies
and alternating
downgrades of banks and sovereigns.
All these problems can be avoided
altogether: they are the result of the
government borrowing in a securities
market characterised by a large
number of short-term speculative
transactions.
This was similarly a problem for banks and their funding.
But the ECB on
8 December 2011 rightly decided to allow banks to become less
reliant on
securitised and traded debt, by substituting direct credit lines
from
the ECB (the long-term refinancing operation, LTRO). This happened
after
we had presented to about 50 senior staff members at the ECB our
proposal of how governments could similarly sidestep their funding
problems, and at the same time solve several other problems. Why should
the government rely on the bond market for its funding needs, under
current conditions? It is a fact that the prime rate for borrowing from
banks is far lower than the benchmark sovereign issuance yield. This is
an anomaly resulting from the current financial crisis. Governments need
to respond to this anomaly by exiting the bond market.
We advise
governments to stop issuing government bonds. So when the next
tranche of
government bonds are about to mature, where will governments
obtain the
funding from?
Many commentators have proposed to ask the ECB to step in.
However, this
is problematic for many reasons, and far less efficient than
our
proposal. It also renders governments at the mercy of the ECB and its
European unification agenda. But why do many observers anyway think the
central bank should step in? Because they believe that the central bank
is the main creator of the money supply. This is simply not true. The
fact is that central banks only create about 3% of the money supply. A
full 97% of the money supply is created by the private sector: the
ordinary commercial banks in each country. This ability to create the
bulk of the money supply makes them far superior to the bond
market
{p. 10} We thus advise governments to enter into loan contracts
with the
commercial banks in their country. In other words, governments
should
not borrow via the issuance of tradable securities, but through
direct
credit lines from their banks. 10
Some observers believe that
banks could not do this, because they 'do
not have the money'. Well, that's
true. But this is true for any loan
granted by a bank. Which is why banks do
not lend money, they create it:
banks are allowed to invent a deposit in the
borrower's account
(although no new deposit was made by anyone from outside
the bank) and
since they function as the settlement system of the economy,
nobody can
tell the difference between these invented deposits and 'real'
ones.
Actually, those 97% of the money supply are invented in this
way.
Others object that a mere switch from government bonds to bank loan
contracts would not change much, or even anything. Well, in that case
they could not possibly object to trying it out. And if they did try it
out, they would be surprised at the significant difference it makes – a
difference of night and day:
This simple switch in funding, which I
call 'enhanced debt management'
has a number of major advantages:
1.
The borrowing rate is substantially lower. Governments receive,
according to
Basel banking regulations, the lowest risk-weighting
(zero). Thus they can
borrow from banks at their favoured-client rate,
which is the prime rate.
The prime rate has been substantially lower
than the sovereign bond rate
throughout this financial crisis. In the
case of Italy, we estimate that
about E10bn can be saved in the next two
years alone on lower interest
charges. Furthermore, governments will
deal with stable borrowing rates that
are fixed throughout the loan
contract period (say 3 years). Movements in
the bond market become far
less relevant.
2. The banks do not have to
mark these loans to market. Moreover, they
are not affected by downgrades
from credit rating agencies. This severs
the vicious negative feedback loop
between banks and governments. At the
same time, however, the banks can use
these loans fully as collateral
with the ECB for funding, as the ECB's
announcement of 8 December 2011
makes clear.
3. Instead of a negative
feedback loop, there is now a positive feedback
loop: banks will be happy to
lend to governments, for one, because
sovereigns carry a zero risk weighting
according to BCBS rules. This
means that banks will need zero new capital to
back these loans.
10 I have presented this proposal in Japan in the
1990s: Richard A.
Werner (1998), Minkanginkoukarano kariire de keikitaisaku
wo okonaeba
issekinichou, Economist (Japan), 14 July, 1998; It was also
published in
English in the FT: Richard A. Werner (2000). Japan's plan to
borrow from
banks deserves praise. Financial Times, 9 Feburary 2000; I also
personally explained it to government officials in Japan, among others,
to Hirohiko Kuroda, then vice-minister of international finance, who
liked it enough, as he told me, to pass it on to Andrew Smithers on his
visit to Tokyo – who in turn wrote it up in his reports, whence it
circulated in the City. It then came to be endorsed by Tim Congdon as
well as Martin Wolf. It is explained in greater detail in Richard A.
Werner (2005), New Paradigm in Macroeconomics, Palgrave Macmillan; A
recent application to Europe is in: Helmut Siekmann and Richard Werner
(2011), Eine einfache und gerechte Lösung der Schuldenkrise,
Börsen-Zeitung, 09.12.2011, Nummer 238, page 7.
{p. 11} 4. The main
business of banks is to lend, but they are not
lending to the rest of the
economy due to their risk aversion. Thus they
do not generate earnings to
retain and rebuild their balance sheets.
Through my enhanced debt
management, banks will rapidly grow their
balance sheets and earn decent
income. Instead of primary market bond
underwriters, such as Goldman Sachs,
earning large fees in cosy
relationships with semi-privatised public debt
management agencies,
banks will be the beneficiaries of this business. 5.
Despite the above
major advantages, which alone would make this a no-
brainer, the single
most important advantage of switching public funding to
loan contracts
from banks has not yet been mentioned: it will boost domestic
credit
creation – turning bank credit growth from zero or negative growth to
positive growth (of about 3% in the case of Italy). This will increase
demand and the money supply, ending the current debt deflation spiral,
and generate nominal GDP growth, in the case of Italy between 3% and 4%
above the growth otherwise possible. (This is the result of our
empirical nominal GDP model based on our Quantity Theory of
Credit).
Enhanced debt management that exits securitised debt markets and
relies
on bank credit from the commercial banks will trigger an economic
recovery. It is the necessary second half of the policy that would
render the ECB's LTRO successful: as we have seen, bank credit is
currently still contracting, despite the LTRO. This would change
drastically.
The economic recovery, triggered by a recovery in bank
credit creation,
will increase tax revenues. Suddenly the negative spiral
will be turned
into a positive one.
There is also a historical
precedent for this type of policy: the
economics is the same as that of the
system of short-term bills of trade
issued by semi-public entities in the
years from 1933 onwards in
Germany, which were bought by the German banks,
hence increasing bank
credit creation. These are known as 'Mefo Wechsel',
after one of the
issuers, the Metallurgical Research Corporation. This
method was
introduced by Dr. Hjalmar Schacht, President of the Reichsbank,
the
German central bank, in 1933. 11
The method, which he called
'silent funding', was highly successful. As
I have argued elsewhere, the
sharp German economic recovery from over
20% unemployment in early 1933 to
virtually full employment by the end
of 1936 was the result of the ensuing
expansion in bank credit creation
– in other words, it was the funding of
fiscal policy through credit
creation that caused the recover, not fiscal
stimulus per se. Japan's
experience of the 1990s has proven how even far
larger fiscal expansions
will not boost the economy at all if they are not
funded by credit
creation (see Werner, 2003, 2005).
In the 1930s the
bills of trade were a preferable method at the time,
instead of direct loan
contracts with banks, since banks did not have to
mark securities to market,
and credit rating agencies did not exist. The
method I have suggested, of
direct loans by banks to governments, is a
modern version that is more
suitable to today's regulatory and financial
market environment. The effect
of stimulating a recovery will be the same.
11 For further details, see
Werner (2003).
{p. 12} Further reading:
Werner R. A. (1995). How
to create a recovery through 'Quantitative
Monetary Easing'. The Nihon
Keizai Shinbun (Nikkei), 2 September 1995
(morning edition), p.26 (in
Japanese). English Translation available at
http://eprints.soton.ac.uk/340476/
Werner
R. A. (1997). 'Towards a new monetary paradigm: a quantity
theorem of
disaggregated credit', with evidence from Japan. Kredit und
Kapital, Duncker
and Humblot, Berlin, 30, pp. 276–309. available at
http://eprints.soton.ac.uk/36569/
Werner
R. A. (2002), 'How to Get Growth in Japan', Central Banking, vol.
XIII, no.
2, November 2002, pp. 48-54
Werner R. A. (2003), Princes of the Yen,
Japan's Central Bankers and the
Structural Transformation of the Economy, M.
E. Sharpe
Werner R. A. (2005), New Paradigm in Macroeconomics. Palgrave
MacMillan.
Werner, R. A. (2009). Financial crises in Japan during the
20th century.
Bankhistorisches Archiv, 47, 98-123, available at
http://eprints.soton.ac.uk/186635/1/Werner_Bankhistor_Archiv_2009_postfinal.pdf
(3)
ECB keeping the threat of financial Armageddon alive, to coerce
Europe into
a deeper union
http://www.bloomberg.com/news/print/2011-10-25/euro-s-self-styled-saviors-could-be-its-greatest-enemies-view.html
Euro’s
Self-Styled Saviors Could Be Its Greatest Enemies: View
By the Editors -
Oct 25, 2011
Europe’s leaders urgently need to convince the market that
they can
prevent financial distress in Greece and elsewhere from bringing
down
the banking system and infecting bigger countries such as Italy and
France.
Instead, as they meet today for their second summit in four days,
they’re engaged in a high-stakes game of chicken.
On one side, French
President Nicolas Sarkozy has proposed raising the
money needed -- at least
3 trillion euros ($4.2 trillion), by Bloomberg
View’s calculations -- from
the European Central Bank, the only
institution that can credibly pledge
such a large sum.
On the other side, central bank officials, with the
backing of German
Chancellor Angela Merkel, are holding out. They don’t want
to pony up
for a full rescue without first fixing key flaws in the euro
area, such
as the lack of a unified fiscal authority with the power to
impose
budget discipline on member countries. Such reforms require treaty
revisions that could take years to push through, suggesting the ECB
won’t be providing the firepower Europe needs to end its crisis anytime
soon.
As a result, barring some miracle, Europe’s leaders will test
markets’
patience with yet another inadequate bailout -- if they reach a
deal at
all. Early reports suggest private creditors might be pushed to
write
down Greece’s debt by about 50 percent, not quite the full reckoning
required to draw a line under sovereign defaults. Plans to enhance the
European Financial Stability Facility might boost its lending or
guarantee capacity to 1 trillion euros or so, far short of what is
needed to recapitalize banks and protect solvent governments from market
attacks.
Keeping Armageddon Alive
Central bank officials may
be hoping that by keeping the threat of
financial Armageddon alive, they can
coerce the region’s people and
governments into moving toward the deeper
union that the euro’s creators
envisioned. If so, they’re making an
extremely risky bet. Market turmoil
is pushing up borrowing costs for banks
and companies at a time when
economic indicators are pointing toward a
recession, making the
financial positions of otherwise solvent governments
increasingly
precarious.
Consider Italy. If its nominal economic
growth averages 2.6 percent, as
the International Monetary Fund forecasts,
it must run a primary budget
surplus (excluding debt-service payments) of
1.9 percent of gross
domestic product to keep its debt burden from growing
-- a target it is
on track to meet next year. If the average growth rate
falls to 1
percent, however, the required surplus rises to 3.6 percent of
GDP --
roughly an added 26 billion euros a year.
At some point, the
ECB will inevitably have to step in, as it already
has done by buying some
169.5 billion euros in government bonds. The
longer the crisis lasts, the
greater the cost will be, and the greater
the chance it will overwhelm even
the central bank, triggering a global
meltdown far worse than what the world
suffered in 2008 and 2009.
To be sure, ECB officials do have a point. To
reassure markets, the
central bank would have to put up enough money to
guarantee all new
bonds issued by Greece, Portugal, Ireland, Spain, Italy,
France and
Belgium. In doing so, it could encourage governments to act even
more
irresponsibly. As Bloomberg View has pointed out, only by giving up
some
fiscal sovereignty can the highly divergent economies of the euro area
make their currency union work in the long run. Aside from enforceable
budget controls, a closer union should include the kind of federal
transfers, such as unemployment insurance and infrastructure spending,
that can help struggling countries as they try to get back in
sync.
Ideally, Europe’s leaders would find a way to fast-track the deeper
reforms. There won’t be much left to fix, though, if they don’t succeed
in forestalling financial disaster in the meantime. It would be a cruel
irony if, in their efforts to build a better union, Europe’s central
bankers ended up destroying it.
To contact the Bloomberg View
editorial board: view@bloomberg.net
No comments:
Post a Comment
Note: Only a member of this blog may post a comment.