Richard Werner and Ambrose Evans-Pritchard: get rid of debt and dethrone
the
bankers
Richard Werner is Professor and Chair of International Banking at
the
University of Southampton. Previously he was Assistant Professor of
Economics at Sophia University in Tokyo. He spent over a decade working
in Asia, including at the Bank of Japan, the Japanese Ministry of
Finance, Jardine Fleming Securities (Asia) Ltd, the Asian Development
Bank and as asset allocator of a major pension fund.
Werner is on
"our" side. He's been taking on the bnanking establishment,
and is not much
liked there.
The Foreword to Where Does Money Come From? (item 1) is by
Charles A. E.
Goodhart, Professor Emeritus of Banking and Finance, London
School of
Economics
(1) Richard Werner: Maatricht Treaty prohibits
the direct financing of
government spending by the nation's central
bank
(2) Richard Werner: Seigniorage and banks' 'special profits' ie interest
as a private tax
(3) Richard Werner asks: Could the government directly
create money itself?
(4) Werner: governments can create money without debt,
and use it to run
the economy, like Kublai Khan
(5) Werner: Banking in
Ancient and Modern History; Chinese paper money
(6) Werner: The German and
Japanese challenge
(7) US Treasury criticizes Germany’s chronic trade
surplus
(8) WE in the Anglosphere are Greece; the Asia Model countries are
Germany
(9) John Craig: demand deficits in East Asia cause excess
consumption,
bubbles & debt in West
(10) John Craig: Asia Model
current account surpluses recycled into
further expansion of production
capacity
(11) What if we adopted a system where the Banks did not create our
Money?
(12) Ambrose Evans-Pritchard: IMF's epic plan to conjure away debt and
dethrone bankers
(1) Richard Werner: Maatricht Treaty prohibits the
direct financing of
government spending by the nation's central
bank
Where Does Money Come From? A Guide to the UK Monetary and Banking
System
by Josh Ryan-Collins, Tony Greenham, Richard Werner and Andrew
Jackson
London: nef (new economics foundation), 2011
{p. 78} One
of the most important rules of the Treaty in relation to
money creation is
Article 101 EC (now known as Article 126 of the Treaty
on the Functioning of
the European Union (TFEU)). This prohibits the
direct financing of
government spending by the nation's central bank.
This includes any
overdraft credit facility and the direct purchase of
any debt instrument
(i.e. gilts, ) treasury bonds) by the central bank.
Article 101 EC does
however allow the central bank to purchase debt
instruments on the secondary
market, i.e. after have previously been
issued to private investors and
started to be traded in money markets
(see Chapter 2, Box 4).
This is
exactly what the UK central bank did during the financial crisis
of
2007/2008. During the period of what was called 'quantitative
easing', the
Bank England did not create new money in the sense of new
purchasing power
in the economy, as is often thought. Rather, it pumped
vast quantities of
central reserves into the banking system via the
purchase of government
bonds (gilts) on the secondary market. It did
not, and, is not permitted to
under Article 101 EC, purchase newly
issued gilts directly from the UK
government. Such action would, of
course, provide the government with newly
created money which could be
spent directly into the economy via government
departments or to reduce
national debt.
ECB has followed a similar
course of action in the eurozone more
recently by buying €45 billion of
Greek bonds and more recently Irish,
Portuguese, Irish, and Italian bonds
from the secondary market in an
attempt to prevent a loss of confidence in
the European sovereign debt
bond markets.
These EU rules ensure that
when government spending exceeds taxes
governments are forced to borrow
funds from the market and run up a
deficit, rather than finance the deficit
or increase public spending
through new central money creation. This is why
the interest rates on
government debt of different European countries,
particularly since the
financial crisis, are the focus of so much media
attention. If the
interest rates on government debt reach a certain level,
the markets may
lose confidence in the government's capacity to repay its
loans, or roll
over its debt, pushing interest rates even higher until
eventually the
country faces the prospect of default. As political economist
Geoffrey
Ingham argues, the Maastricht Treaty effectively removed the power
of
money creation from individual states and subjected them to market
discipline: {continued on p. 79, after Box 9}
{p. 79} The latter
constraint [article 10] is aimed at preventing
individual states ftom
monetizing their debt, in the time-honoured
fashion, which would compromise
the ECB's [European central bank's]
absolute control of the Production of
money. Now that individual member
central banks cannot monetize their
states' debts, budget deficits must
be financed directly in the money market
- like those of any private
corporation.
{end quote}
These
restrictions on credit creation do not apply to 'publicly owned
credit
institutions', which have full credit creation powers and are
treated in
exactly the same way as private banks by the central bank.
Furthermore, as
the European sovereign debt crisis unfolded, the ECB has
interpreted some of
the rules 'flexibly', so that its credibility and
enforceability in case of
non-compliance by a member government are now
somewhat more doubtful.
Finally, as will be discussed below, these rules
do not prevent the
government borrowing from commercial banks which in
turn will create new
money, to fund the public sector borrowing requirement.
How does the
government then 'spend'? Like me and you, and unlike
commercial banks, in
order to spend the government first needs to obtain
money from somewhere.
Generally, this spending is either funded from
{p. 80} revenue, proceeds
from profitable government-operated
enterprises or services, national
insurance contributions and taxes, or
through borrowing.
4.2.1 The
Consolidated Fund
Like any organisation that wishes both to receive and
spend money, the
government has bank accounts. However, unlike most
organisations, the
government's primary bank accounts are held at the Bank
of England. The
oldest of the accounts is the Consolidated Fund (CF) (Figure
16), whA
was established in 1787 as 'one fund into which shall flow every
stream
of public revenue and from which shall come the supply for every
service.' Administered by HM Treasury, the Consolidated Fund can
essentially be bought of as the government's current account. The taxes
collected by HM venue and Customs (HMRQ are the primary inflows into the
Consolidated Fund (Figure 16). However, if the government is running a
deficit, then pending outflows exceed tax inflows. To make the account
balance, the difference must be made up through government
borrowing.
(2) Richard Werner: Seigniorage and banks' 'special profits'
ie interest
as a private tax
{p. 68} Box 8: Seigniorage, cash and
bank's 'special profits'
The Bank of England sells bank notes to
commercial banks. They sell
these notes at face value (a E10 note sells for
E10), yet the cost of
printing a E10 note is just a few pennies. The
difference between the
face value and cost of production gives the Bank of
England substantial
profit. This profit from the creation of money is known
as
'seigniorage', and is paid over to the Treasury, where it can be used to
fund government spending or to reduce taxation. In the years 2000 and
2009 this seigniorage amounted to nearly E18 billion.
The growth of
digital commercial bank money, vis-a-vis government issued
cash, can be een
to have the effect of significantly reducing this
seigniorage profit to the
government proportionate to the total money
supply. Commercial banks do not
generate seigniorage themselves as they
issue credit which will, at some
point, be repaid in full. However, as
we discussed in Section 2.4 on
Fractional Reserve Banking, commercial
banks can be seen to generate
'special profits' from their power to
issue money in the form of credit
through the interest charged upon
loans and used overdraft
facilities.
Huber and Robertson suggest the interest charged on the
issuance of
money by banks can be viewed as a 'money tax', since the
government
could issue non-interest bearing money directly in to the
economy. They
also argue that bank's {sic} enjoy a form-of additional
'special profit'
because they don't have to first borrow this money like
other
organisations. This 'special profit' can be thought as equivalent to
the
central bank's base rate over the course of the loan.
The total
profits arising are then the rate of interest charged on the
loan (e.g. 8
per cent), added to the base rate (e.g. 2 per cent) = 10
per cent, minus any
interest paid by the bank to the customer on any
portions of the loan that
the customer has not yet spent. This is
opposed to an interest rate 'spread'
profit of 8 per cent - 2 per cent =
6 per cent. Using this methodology,
Huber and Robertson calculated that
in 2000 the 'special profits' generated
through this were E21 billion.
(3) Richard Werner asks: Could the
government directly create money itself?
{p. 79} Box 9: Could the
government directly create money itself?
There are many historical
examples of governments funding fiscal
shortfalls through the issuance of
government money. This was done in
the UK during WWI, and prior to this via
the elaborate system of tally
sticks deployed between the eleventh and
nineteenth centuries (Section
2.3) Similarly, the governments of Germany,
Japan, and the USA issued at
times significant amounts of government money,
mainly during the
nineteenth century.
While the issuance of
government money to fund fiscal expenditure is
often thought to be
inflationary, this need not be the case, especially
if limited by the amount
of money-supply expansion needed to reach the
growth potential of the
economy. As has been argued by Huber and
Robertson and others,
government-created money may represent an
efficient use of the monetary
system to minimise the tax burden and
maximise value for tax-payers. No
servicing costs in the form of
interest and interest on interest (compound
interest) are incurred. This
could be a substantial benefit at a time when
many a government spends
as much or even more on compounded interest on
their debts than on their
core government expenditure programmes (see also
Box 8 on 'seigniorage'
{see below}). Exploring alternative methods of
creating new money is
beyond the scope of this book, but these historical
examples are
important to illustrate that alternative systems are not just
possible
but have been tested and been effective.
{end Box 9}
(4)
Werner: governments can create money without debt, and use it to run
the
economy, like Kublai Khan
New Paradigm in Macroeconomics: Solving the
Riddle of Japanese
Macroeconomic Performance
by Richard A.
Werner
Palgrave, London, 2005
{p. 258} The most efficient way to
fund fiscal expenditure
There is a fourth option of funding government
expenditure which has
also been ignored by most of the literature. The first
three all share
one common drawback: they create debt, which needs to be
serviced
through interest and interest on interest. In the case of most
industrialized nations, but especially in the case of the US and Japan,
these compound interest liabilities are substantial. They will have to
be serviced by generations of taxpayers, while public expenditures (such
as on public services, healthcare, education, and so on) will have to be
cut in order to save money to be able to service the accumulated debt
mountain. Economically, this is a highly inefficient, unproductive and
inequitable allocation of resources.
There is an option to fund
government expenditure, which has the
advantage of no quantity crowding out,
but also does not suffer from the
disadvantage of incurring debt. It is thus
the most desirable, efficient
and equitable method: this is the option for
governments to create money
directly and use it to fund their expenditure,
just as Kublai Khan did
in thirteenth-century China, or as the US government
did during several
stages of its history. In these cases, no debt is
incurred, and no
interest liabilities weigh on future generations of
taxpayers.
Indeed, the US Constitution, largely under the influence of
Thomas
Jefferson (an opponent of privately-owned central banks), explicitly
reserved the right of money creation for the US government. Since the
creation of the privately-owned Federal Reserve banks in 1913, this
option was increasingly avoided, thus incurring significant government
debt and substantial interest liabilities. One of the few presidents to
challenge the de facto monopoly to create credit that the banking system
and the Federal Reserve banks enjoy was John F. Kennedy, who ordered the
issuance of 'United States Notes' in 1963 with one of his last executive
orders (No. 11,110).13 This government money had the same design as the
more common 'Federal Reserve Notes', but instead was entitled 'United
States Notes' (compare Figures 18.3 and 18.4). Further, it was only
graced by the seal of the US Treasury, and did not have any seal linked
to the Federal Reserve system. After Kennedy's death this practice has
not been repeated. Since then, interest liabilities of the US population
have mounted.
In line with this argument, Joseph Stiglitz has called
for the Japanese
government to issue government paper money. 14 In Japan,
this policy was
last implemented in the early Meiji era. To fund stimulatory
fiscal
policy through the issuance of paper money is economically more
efficient than borrowing. In practice, the technique can still be
improved upon, however: paper note issuance is somewhat cumbersome,
carries (small) production costs and, most of all, is limited in
potential maximum scope by the fact that only about 5% of all
transactions make use of paper money. Therefore an improved version of
this funding policy, which allows the government to
{p. 259} {photos
& captions}
Figure 18.3 The standard Federal Reserve Note
The
standard five dollar 'Federal Reserve Note' is entitled as such and
carries
the seal of the Federal Reserve system (on the left) and the
seal of the US
Treasury (on the right)
Figure 18.4 The United States Note
In
1963, President Kennedy ordered the issuance of government paper
money, with
the same design as the Federal Reserve Notes, but entitled
'United States
Note' and bearing, only the seal of the US Treasury (on
the right)
{end
photos & captions}
create larger volumes of credit, would be for the
Finance Ministry (or,
in the case of the US, the Treasury) to institute
credit creation on its
own accounts, the same way that currently the central
banks and the
commercial banks create credit. This could be achieved if
Milton
Friedman's (1982) advice was heeded, which constitutes the
culmination
of his decades of research into the functioning and economic
implications of the Federal Reserve system, namely to fold the functions
of the central bank into the Treasury, by rendering 'the Federal Reserve
a bureau in the Treasury under the secretary of the Treasury' (Friedman,
1982, p. 118).15 ==
The Friedman reference is to p. 18
at
Friedman, Milton (1982), Monetary policy, theory and practice, Journal
of Money, Credit and Banking, vol. 14, no. 1, February, pp.
98-118.
Werner has a more detailed quote from Friedman (same source) in
Princes
of the Yen at p. 247:
"The only two alternatives that do seem
to me feasible over the longer
run are either to make the Federal Reserve a
bureau in the Treasury
under the secretary of the Treasury, or to put the
Federal Reserve under
direct congressional control. Either involves
terminating the so-called
independence of the system. But either would
establish a strong
incentive for the Fed to produce a stabler monetary
environment than we
have had."
(5) Werner: Banking in Ancient and
Modern History; Chinese paper money
New Paradigm in
Macroeconomics
{p. 164} In Ptolemaic Egypt 'payments were effected by
transfer from one
account to another, without money passing' (Rostovtzeff,
1941, quoted by
Davies, 1994, pp. 52ff). Papyri served for bookkeeping and
receipt
issuance. The bank books distinguished credit and debit entries." A
central bank was established in Alexandria. Next, 'Rome and
Constantinople became the main inheritors of the banking wisdom of the
ancient ~#orld' (Davies, 1994, p. 91). Banking has existed in Rome since
at least 310 BC. Wax-covered writing tablets served as deposit or loan
receipts and the collateralization of land to secure loans played an
important role. With bankers becoming influential senators and vice
versa, links to the political leadership were apparent and controversial
- Julius Caesar was involved in banking himself (Andreau, 1999).11
Between the third and sixth centuries AD banking houses are known to
have existed in Europe in the form of deposit-taking silversmiths
(Andreau, 1999). Meanwhile, bankers have been instrumental in the rapid
economic development of China since the Song Dynasty of the tenth
century. The Mongolian empire spread advanced banking practices across
much of Euroasia. Finally, over the past millennium, banking dynasties
have played a major and well-documented economic and political role in
the whole of Europe. To name a few, there were Italian bankers who at
one stage dominated European banking, influential banking houses in the
Low Countries, and even organizations such as the Knights Templar who
engaged in sophisticated, international banking activities, beginning in
the eleventh century. Bills of exchange were 'discounted' by banking
houses to circumvent the ban on charging interest (usury). In England,
an ancient form of issuing receipts were the wooden 'tallies', eight- or
nine-inch-long sticks carved from hazel, with notches to mark different
amounts. They acted as bills of exchange and stimulated banking
activities for centuries.12
Wars were often funded by banks, whether
it was William of Orange's
invasion of Britain or Napoleon's international
campaigns. Indeed, a
cursory survey of the history of banking appears to
coincide with the
history of the rise (and fall) of advanced economies and
empires. There
are few advanced civilizations that did not use credit
systems. Sparta
appears to have been one such exception, which perhaps
contributed to
the rivalry perceived by banking-dominated Athens. In almost
all cases,
these banking systems led to the'development of economies
dominated by
non-cash and non-money transactions. Petty transactions for
day-to-day
expenses by the ordinary population were usually conducted with
the use
of commodity money or cash, as they are today. But these amounted to
a
small fraction of total trans-_ action values.
Banking, we thus
find, has been at the heart of human economic activity
for thousands of
years. It has also been an important aspect of the
political economy, and
via its link to warfare contributed to reshaping
world history.' Given these
facts, we should expect banking to either
constitute the crucial link
between the monetary/financial side and the
'real economy' or at
least
{p. 165} provide a major illumination of it. So why have banking
activities been neglected for so long by economists?13 When banks were
analysed, they were viewed merely as extensions of the 'money'-based
structures postulated by deductive theory. In Schumpeter's (1954)
words:
The huge system of credits and debits, of claims and debts, by
which
capitalist society carries on its daily business of production and
consumption is ... built up step by step by introducing claims to money
or credit instruments that act as substitutes for legal tender and are
allowed indeed to affect its functioning in many ways but not to oust it
from its fundamental role in the theoretical picture of the financial
structure ... The legal constructions, too ... were geared to a sharp
distinction between -money as the only genuine and ultimate means of
payment and the credit instrument that embodied a claim to money. But
logically, it is by no means clear that the most useful method is to
start from the coin ... in order to proceed to the credit transactions
of reality. It may be more useful to start from these in the first
place, to look upon capitalist finance as a clearing system that cancels
claims and debts and carries forward the differences - so that 'money'
payments come in only as a special case without any particfilarly
fundamental importance. (p. 717)
To identify the other special
feature of banks, we need to research how
banks came about. While so far too
few clay tablets have been found or
translated to answer this question in
the case of the first banking
systems in Babylon, we can use the case study
of more recent
introductions of banking systems, such as the development of
the
goldsmith bankers in London. Since they were banks in every sense, the
key empirical features of their development should lend themselves to a
degree of abstraction and generalization.
Chinese paper
money
However, first a brief look at an alternative financial system will
be
useful, in order to put banks into sharper contrast. This is the
monetary system of the Mongol Empire, including China, as it is
described in the thirteenth 1~entury. Marco Polo was a trained merchant,
and his description of Kublai
Khan's financial system is highly
Illuminating. The Khan's government
issued paper money, which was legal
tender. It appears that the majority
of transactions were actually
transacted through this paper money. In
this case, it is apparent that the
definition for money in any quantity
equation would be the stock of paper
money issued by the government's,
mint. Thus the government was directly in
control of the money supply
and could stimulate demand by creating more
paper money, or slow the
economy by taking paper Out of circulation. This
was done through 'open
market operations', which
{p. 166} are also
described by Polo. The description is well worth
citing at
length:
{quote} It is in this city of Khan-balik that the Great Khan has
his
mint; and it "' so organized that you might well say that he has
mastered the art o alchemy. I will demonstrate this to you here and now.
You must kn that he has money made for him ... out of the bark of troes
- to be precis from mulberry trees (the same whose leaves furnish food
for silkworms) . all these papers are sealed with the seal of the Great
Khan. The proce u of issue is as formal and as authoritative as if they
were made of pure gol or silver. On each piece of money several
specially appointed officia write their names, each setting his own
stamp. When it is completed due form, the chief of the officials deputed
by the Khan dips in cinnab the seal or bull assigned to him and stamps
it on the top of the piece money so that the shape of the seal in
vermilion remains impressed upo' it. And then the money is authentic.
And if anyone were to forge it, h would suffer the extreme
penalty.
Of this money the Khan has such a quantity made that with it he
coul buy
all the treasure in the world. With this currency he orders all
payments
to be made throughout every province and kingdom and region his
empire.
And no one dares refuse it on pain of losing his life. And assure
you
that all the peoples and populations who are subject to his ruli are
perfectly willing to accept these papers in payment, since wherev they
go they pay in the same currency, whether for goods or for pearls o
precious stones or gold or silver. With these pieces of paper they can
bu anything and pay for anything ...
Several times a year parties of
traders arrive with pearls and preciou
stones and gold and silver and other
valuables, such as cloth of gold an
silk, and surrender them all to the
Great Khan. The Khan then summon
twelve experts, who are chosen for the task
and have special knowled of
it, and bids them examine the wares that the
traders have brought and
pay for them what they judge to be their true
value. The twelve experts
duly examine the wares and pay the value in the
paper currency of which
I have spoken. The traders accept it willingly,
because they can spend
it afterwards -on the various goods they buy
throughout the Great Khan's
dorminions ...
Let me tell you further
that several times a year a flat goes forth
through the towns that all those
who have gems and pearls and gold and
silver must bring them to the Great
Khan's mint. This they do, and in
such abundance that it is past all
reckoning; and they are all paid in
paper money. By this means the Great
Khan acquires all the gold and
silver and pearls and precious stones of all
his territories ... And all
the Khan's armies are paid with this sort of
money. I have now told you
how it comes about that the Great Khan must have,
as indeed he has, more
treasure than anyone else in the world. I may go
further and affirm that
all the
{p. 167} world's great potentates put
together have not such riches as
belong to the Great Khan alone. (Polo,
1987, pp. 147ff.)
Marco Polo's description must have seemed exaggerated
to his fellow
Europeans at the time, but we now know that he was giving what
amounts
to a fairly precise description of the monetary system prevailing at
this time in the Mongolian Empire. Even his estimation of the Khan's
wealth as far exceeding that of his counterparts in the rest of the
world might well have been accurate. The government in the Mongolian
Empire could not only control nominal economic growth, but also allocate
resources at will. According to descriptions of the Chinese economy at
the time, it was flourishing.
At the time, European kings and princes
had far less control over the
economy. This is because the rulers did not
understand the true nature
of money and therefore never realized that they
could issue paper money.
instead, they believed that money had to be in the
form 4 gold or other
precious metals. The problem was that in this case it
is impossible for
the government to control the money supply at will and
allocate
resources. Rulers spent significant resources on alchemy, in an
attempt
to produce gold. While they failed, this delivered positive side
effects
by advancing chemistry. It also demonstrates thaL rulers did seek to
exert power over the economy through the control of the money supply.
But they failed and thus European governments never gained nearly as
much control over the economy as Kublai Khan's government
enjoyed.
The alchemy of banking
This was also largely the
situation in England in the seventeenth
century. Precious metals and coins
made thereof were considered the only
form of money. However, it was a time
of war, lack of security, plague
and fire. In this time of insecurity,
luxuries were less in demand. Thus
also 'the ordinary demand for goldsmiths
to make objects of gold and
silver for the customers had ... practically
ceased' (Davies, 1994, p.
250). However, there was demand for another
activity the jewellers could
offer: dealing in precious metals and
originally focusing on turning
them into handcrafted jewellery; they
naturally had stocks of precious
metals, and the necessary safes and private
security staff - if not
small private armies - to protect their property.
Dealing in gold and
silver, they were already independently wealthy and thus
considered
trustworthy. Therefore the general public began to use
'goldsmiths'
safes as a secure place for people's jewels, bullion and coins'
(Davies,
1994, pp. 249ff.). This storage and safekeeping business generated
small
fees. When gold was deposited with a goldsmith, he would write a
receipt
to certify that it was in his custody, which would be presented in
case
of withdrawals. As this practice became widespread,
depositors
{p. 168} would soon begin to pay for purchases by handing over
their
deposit receipts, and thus transferring the ownership of their gold to
the seller. To facilitate such cashless transactions, the use of unnamed
deposit receipts became more widespread. The diary of Samuel Pepys
mentions his sending of a deposit note to his father of over £600 in
1668. The deposit receipts had become paper money.
However, this
European form of paper money was crucially different in
its function and
implication from the paper money used in Polo's time in
China: it was issued
not by the government but by a private group of
businessmen.
(6)
Werner: The German and Japanese challenge
New Paradigm in
Macroeconomics
{p. 333} The German and Japanese challenge
in many
ways, all of these findings are not new. The new kind of
economics has an
old predecessor. So has neoclassical economics: The
direct forerunner of
modern mainstream economics, operating with simiiar
assumptions and coming
to similar conclusions, was British classical
economics of the nineteenth
century. It already operated according to
the deductivist paradigm. At the
time Britain was the world's leading
economic and political power, running a
world empire and mass-producing
advanced industrial output that required a
market. Classical economics
appeared to serve a useful purpose for the
empire: it recommended that
other countries did not need to develop
competing industries, or use
government intervention, but instead should
open their markets, without
charging any tariffs, to British exports. This
would - said the British
classical economics - improve their welfare. Not
surprisingly, classical
economics was used to advance British power
worldwide.
Thus it came that German economists were also confronted with
the
British classical school of thought. The German economists, like
scientists from other disciplines, at the time used the inductive
methodology. So they decided to empirically evaluate the British
classical theories and their claims. Friedrich List, one of the first
and most influential development economists, decided to investigate the
British claim that deregulation, liberalization and opening up to free
trade and free markets was the path to prosperity and economic
development (just like it has been the Washington claim for the past
decades). He developed the testable hypothesis that, if this claim was
true, the major episodes of successful national economic development
should be somehow linked to free trade and free market
policies.
Studying the facts by meticulously researching the historical
record of
economic development of the major economic powers over the
centuries,
List concluded that there was not one major economic power that
owed its
successful development to free trade and free market policies. His
conclusion still stands - although wehow have the benefit of 150 years
of further, and better, data on the world economy. List is particularly
insightful on British economic development. He found that although
British leaders were loudest in propagating the free market paradigm,
British economic development was due to trade restrictions,
protectionism, government intervention, industrial policy and other
'visible hands'. Until about the fifteenth and early sixteenth
centuries, Britain indeed followed the precepts of free market economics
by allowing laissez-faire trade and focusing on its comparative
advantage. As a result it remained primarily a nation of shepherds,
selling raw wool to foreign merchants. Economic prosperity did not grow
significantly. Britain remained poor and underdeveloped. Researchers on
Modern-day developing countries have identified the reason: focusing on
low-value-added primary commodities will not enhance welfare.
High-value-added items will be imported, but their relative prices rise
over time,
{p. 334} while that of commodities falls - thus resulting
in a steady
deterioration of the terms of trade. Balance of payments crises
and
indebtedness follow.
In Britain's case this took the form of the
Crown jewels being pawned to
the dominating German traders. When the British
leadership realized that
the invisible hand was not doing much for the
country, free trade was
abandoned; protectionist trade and industrial
policies were adopted. The
government intervened by importing foreign
know-how in high-value-added
textile manufacturing - through importing
experts from Flanders (as the
now common surname Fleming attests), banning
the import of processed
wool products, stimulating domestic wool production
through industrial
policy and building a fleet of ships to market its
produce.
The British textile industry was established by government
intervention.
Its mechanization triggered the industrial revolution,
rendering Britain
the top economic and military power. To boost British mass
exports,
convincing public relations activities had to persuade the rest of
the
world to open their markets. Classical economics served this purpose.
Britain itself knew better: while British economists spoke of free trade
and the theory of comparative advantage, the far superior and cheaper
Indian textile produce was banned from Britain.
As List showed, the
empirical facts are similar in the case of the US.
The North American
colonies were explicitly forbidden to manufacture
anything for export and
instead had to focus on their 'comparative
advantage' in agriculture. The
policy of suppressing the creation of
indigenous industries in its American
colonies while forcing them to
purchase the fruits of the 'free markets'
from Britain was identified by
List as a factor in causing the War of
Independence. The US started to
develop rapidly when it replaced the 'free
trade' regime imposed by
Britain with protectionist trade barriers and
government industrial
policy to create high-value-added industries. At the
same time, the
British propaganda of free trade and free markets was copied
in order to
force world markets open for US exports. The rest is
history.
Thus when German economists considered the virtues of classical
economics over a hundred years ago, they rejected it as unrealistic and
inapplicable to reality. Instead, they developed a different kind of
economics that is based on realistic assumptions, such as that people
care about others; that market imperfections are pervasive and that
there is positive scope for fruitful government intervention - for
instance in the purposeful designing of incentive structures and the
allocation of resources to high-value-added industries, within a
framework that aimed at social justice and was guided by both realistic
and ethical considerations. These theories - dubbed variously the German
empiricist approach, the German Historical School or the German ethical
economics - had a profound impact on Japan and other East Asian
countries, which studied them, adopted them and followed their policy
advice.
{p. 335} The leaders, having read their German economists
well, realized
that the laissez-faire policy suggested by Britain would
relegate
developing countries to raw material exporter status and hence low
growth. To achieve high growth, comparative advantage had to be created,
through the visible intervention of government policy, primarily in the
form of clever institutional design, but also in the measured allocation
of resources. The Germans and East Asians used economic regulation to
foster technological development and the development and competitiveness
of targeted high-value-added industries. Furthermore, growth in itself
was not considered the main goal of an economy. For a stable society,
economic justice was also important - and again this would not come
about without a visible hand.
As a result, the Germans and Japanese
consciously created a different
form of capitalism, which maintained market
mechanisms, but ensured that
not shareholders but society at large would be
its main beneficiaries.
Many aspects of the Japanese model were introduced
in the successful
East Asian economies. Instead of serving the few, a form
of capitalism
was born that succeeded in creating a decent quality of life
for the
many. By focusing on mutually beneficial cooperation and
coordination,
the designers of the German and Japanese systems managed to
internalize
externalities (costs and benefits not reflected in markets),
minimize
information costs, mobilize resources and motivate individuals.
They
recognized that people compete in hierarchical fashion and have a
common
desire for justice and fairness of organizational arrangements. They
then succeeded in devising organizational forms that can reap benefits
from cooperation in ways that all participants can consider fair. One
such organizational form was the system of industry associations, which
were a modern incarnation of the medieval guild structure. Due to their
public goods character, resulting cartels often were welfare-enhancing.
The cooperative orientation did not mean that there was no competition.
That was encouraged in the form of competing for moving up ranks in
hierarchies. Much more needs to be said on their approach, but this
remains beyond the scope of the present book (see Werner, 2003c,
2003d,2004c).
Reality-based economics, following the inductivist
approach, was
pioneered by German economists in the nineteenth century.
Their writings
emphasized credit and institutional design. This provides a
final test
of the validity of our approach: if their work was right, then
those
countries that followed their prescriptions, including the direction
and
allocation of credit and the shaping of overall institutions, should
have performed well. These countries were Germany in the twentieth
century, Japan, Korea and Taiwan since the late 1930s, and China since
the 1980s, to name the most important examples. For many decades, their
economic performance has been superior to that of most other countries.
This, then, solves the final enigma, discussed in Chapter 5, namely that
of the puzzlingly high economic growth of these countries.
(7) US
Treasury criticizes Germany’s chronic trade surplus
http://www.telegraph.co.uk/finance/currency/9709882/Germany-displaces-China-as-US-Treasurys-currency-villain.html
Germany
displaces China as US Treasury's currency villain
The US Treasury has
issued a damning criticism of Germany’s chronic
trade surplus in its annual
report on worldwide exchange rate abuse,
although it stopped short of
labelling the country a currency manipulator.
By Ambrose
Evans-Pritchard
6:53PM GMT 28 Nov 2012
Treasury officials told
Congress that internal balances within the
eurozone are disrupting the
global trade structure, with almost nothing
being done by north Europeans
states to curb their huge surpluses.
The report said Germany’s current
account surplus is running at 6.3pc of
GDP, and Holland is even worse at
9.5pc. Yet the countries still cleave
to fiscal austerity policies that
constrict internal demand.
The EU’s new tool for cracking down on
intra-EMU imbalances is
"asymmetric" and does not give "sufficient attention
to countries with
large and sustained external surpluses like
Germany".
While the eurozone as a whole is roughly in trade balance, the
EMU
regime of austerity in the South without offsetting stimulus in the
North is creating a contractinary bias, holding back global
recovery.
The US Treasury said eurozone surplus states have "available
room" for
fiscal stimulus but refuse to act, despite repeated pledges by EU
leaders that more must be done to foster growth. "They have not yet made
any concrete proposals capable of yielding meaningful near-term
results."
Germany's permanent surplus is in stark contrast to the shift
under way
in Asia. China has "partially succeeded in shifting away from a
reliance
on exports for growth", and has slashed its surplus to 2.6pc from
10.1pc
in 2007.
While the yuan remains "significantly overvalued",
China’s has stopped
building reserves to hold down its currency and has seen
a 40pc
appreciation against the dollar since 2005 in real terms.
Double-digit
wage growth is closing thecurrency gap by oither
means.
A chart published in the report shows that Germany has overtaken
China
to become the biggest single source of global trade imbalance, alone
accounting for a large chunk of the US deficit.
Switzerland is top
sinner with a surplus of 13pc GDP, though the report
says the country faces
unique circumstances as a safe-haven battling
deflation.
The Swiss
National Bank has bought $230bn in foreign bonds since mid
2011 to hold the
franc, more than China, Russia, Saudia Arabia, Brazil
and India
combined.
The US Treasury’s shift in focus away from China - and towards
Germany’s
disguised mercantilism - reflects mounting irritation in
Washington over
North Europe’s "free-rider" strategy, which relies on
exploiting global
demand rather than generating it at home.
The US
Treasury said China still needs to do more to wean itself off
investment -
almost 50pc of GDP - and boost consumption instead. It
called for a change
in the tax structure, reform of the big state
enterprises, and an end to
financial controls that force up the savings
rate. There is concern that
China’s surplus will rise again over coming
years unless Beijing pushes
through radical reforms.
The tone of the report is conciliatory, a far
cry from the hot rhetoric
of the US election campaign. Republican candidate
Mitt Romney had vowed
to label China a currency manipulator from "day one",
a move that would
have entailed trade sanctions and an ugly turn in
superpower relations.
A separate report from the International Monetary
Fund said China’s
excess credit growth and investment have moved into
"dangerous
territory" and has begun to impose major costs on China
itself.
The country spending 10pc of GDP more on investment than the
Asian
tigers at the peak of the investment bubble before onset of the East
Asian meltdown in the late 1990s.
The Fund said the excesses are
unlikely to lead to the sort of
sudden-stop crisis seen in Thailand,
Indonesia and Korea during that
episode, since those countries relied on
dollar funding whereas China’s
credit comes from internal savings, but there
is disguised damage
nevertheless. Rampant over-investment acts through
complex channels as a
transfer of income from families and small businesses
to big state
firms, distorting the whole economic system over
time.
The IMF said there is little doubt that investment in plant and
infrastructure has driven China’s great boom over the last thirty years
but the law of diminishing returns is setting in.
"The marginal
contribution of an extra unit of investment to growth has
been falling,
necessitating ever larger increases to generate an equal
amount of growth.
Now with investment to GDP already close to 50
percent, the current growth
model may have run its course," it said.
(8) WE in the Anglosphere are
Greece; the Asia Model countries are Germany
- Peter Myers, December 16,
2012
Collectively, Anglosphere countries have pursued the
"Post-Industrial"
paradigm, believing that we don't need manufacturing.
Germany and the
Asia Model countries have gone the opposite way, with the
result that
the rest of the world is now in debt to them.
We may not
notice that debt, because our Current Account Deficits are
handled quietly.
We Deficit countries pay for our excess imports and
borrowings by handing
over ownership of our assets, little by little.
Our reliance on American
military power has shielded us from the worry
that we might ever have to
repay our debt.
But the crisis in Southern Europe gives warning of a
reckoning one day.
(9) John Craig: demand deficits in East Asia cause
excess consumption,
bubbles & debt in West
Progress Towards
Ending the Global Financial Crisis?
by John Craig
http://cpds.apana.org.au/Teams/Articles/globalization.htm#EndingGFC
[...]
excess savings / demand deficits by Japan, China, and major oil
exporters)
and this gave rise to international financial imbalances.
Large demand
deficits ... would have stifled global economic growth if
they had not been
counter-balanced by their trading partners' (mainly
the US's) willingness
and ability to absorb excess savings and provide
excess demand. That excess
demand was sustained by domestic easy money
policies and capital inflow that
stimulated property inflation (which in
turn encouraged very high levels of
consumer spending as the web-cast
noted) until the bubble burst and gave
rise to the GFC (eg see
Structural Incompatibility Puts Global Growth at
Risk, 2003 and
Impacting the Global Economy, 2009);
there are
cultural factors which have encouraged major East Asian
economies (eg Japan
and China) to accumulate high levels of foreign
exchange reserves (and thus
run current account surpluses) in order to
protect against financial crises.
...
the resulting financial imbalances reflect not only a 'clash' of
financial systems, but also a broader 'clash of civilizations', that has
arguably affected recent history though it has been almost invisible to
Asia-illiterate Western economists and defence analysts (see An
unrecognised clash of financial systems, 2001+; Babes in the Asia Woods,
2009+; and Comments on Australia's Strategic Edge in 2030,
2011);
Alternately the fiscal problem might be resolved, as far as
government
is concerned, by increasing taxes and / or reducing spending, so
as to
stabilize government debts. However, if the US is to maintain current
account deficits (to accommodate excess savings elsewhere), it must
maintain a capital account surplus (ie import capital / increase debt
levels). ...
Without rapidly rising asset values, households and
businesses in the
North America, Europe, Australia etc can't provide the
excess demand
that is needed to sustain structural demand deficits in East
Asia,
emerging economies elsewhere and major oil exporters. And, if rising
asset values were again to provide the basis for spending well in excess
of income, this would recreate conditions like those prior to the GFC
and presumably lead to another crisis ...
(10) John Craig: Asia Model
current account surpluses recycled into
further expansion of production
capacity
http://cpds.apana.org.au/Teams/Articles/competing_civilizations.htm#financial_systems
...
Japan's post WWII economic system involved a mercantilist policy
goal of
creating production capacity far in excess of domestic demand
and without
regard to profitability through the creation of credit by a
tightly
regulated financial system - which resulted in large current
account
surpluses that have been recycled into further expansion of
production
capacity and, in recent decades, into investments in $US
assets (see Why
Japan cannot deregulate its financial system).
(11) What if we adopted a
system where the Banks did not create our Money?
From: Tim OSullivan
<timos2003z@hotmail.com>
Subject:
Monetary Reforms
Date: Tue, 6 Nov 2012 15:15:37 +0000
What If We
Adopted A System Where The Banks Did Not Create Our Money?
By Michael, on
October 22nd, 2012
http://theeconomiccollapseblog.com/archives/what-if-we-adopted-a-system-where-the-banks-did-not-create-our-money
What
if there was a financial system that would eliminate the need for
the
federal government to go into debt, that would eliminate the need
for the
Federal Reserve, that would end the practice of fractional
reserve banking
and that would dethrone the big banks? Would you be in
favor of such a
system?
A surprising new IMF research paper entitled "The Chicago Plan
Revisited" by Jaromir Benes and Michael Kumhof is making waves in
economic circles all over the globe. The paper suggests that the world
would be much better off if we adopted a system where the banks did not
create our money.<http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/wp/2012/wp12202.pdf>
So instead of a system where more money is only created when more debt
is
created, we would have a system of debt-free money that is created
directly
by national governments
<http://theeconomiccollapseblog.com/archives/where-does-money-come-from-the-giant-federal-reserve-scam-that-most-americans-do-not-understand>.
There have been others that have suggested such a system before, but
to
have an IMF research paper actually recommend that such a system be
adopted is a very big deal.
<http://theeconomiccollapseblog.com/archives/debt-free-united-states-notes-were-once-issued-under-jfk-and-the-u-s-government-still-has-the-power-to-issue-debt-free-money>
At the moment, the world is experiencing the biggest debt crisis in
human history, and this proposal is being described as a "radical
solution" that could potentially remedy some of our largest financial
problems. Unfortunately, apologists for the current system are already
viciously attacking this new IMF paper, and of course the big banks
would throw a major fit if such a system was ever to be seriously
contemplated. That is why it is imperative that we educate people about
how money really works. Our current system is in the process of
collapsing and we desperately need to transition to a new one.
One of
the fundamental problems with our current financial system is
that it is
based on debt. Just take a look at the United States. The way
our system
works today, the vast majority of all money is "created"
either when we
borrow money or the government borrows money. Therefore,
the creation of
more money creates more debt.
<http://theeconomiccollapseblog.com/archives/where-does-money-come-from-the-giant-federal-reserve-scam-that-most-americans-do-not-understand>
Under
such a system, it should not be surprising that the total amount
of debt in
the United States is more than 30 times larger than it was
just 40 years
ago.<http://research.stlouisfed.org/fred2/data/TCMDO.txt>
We
don't have to do things this way. There is a better alternative.
National
governments can directly issue debt-free currency into
circulation. The
following is a brief excerpt
<http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/wp/2012/wp12202.pdf>
from the IMF
report...
At the height of the Great Depression a number
of leading U.S.
economists advanced a proposal for monetary reform that
became known as
the Chicago Plan. It envisaged the separation of the
monetary and credit
functions of the banking system, by requiring 100%
reserve backing for
deposits. Irving Fisher (1936) claimed the following
advantages for this
plan: (1) Much better control of a major source of
business cycle
fluctuations, sudden increases and contractions of bank
credit and of
the supply of bank-created money. (2) Complete elimination of
bank runs.
(3) Dramatic reduction of the (net) public debt. (4) Dramatic
reduction
of private debt, as money creation no longer requires simultaneous
debt
creation. We study these claims by embedding a comprehensive and
carefully calibrated model of the banking system in a DSGE model of the
U.S. economy. We find support for all four of Fisher's claims.
Why
should banks be allowed to create money?
That is a very good
question.
Why should sovereign governments ever have to borrow money from
anyone?
That is another very good question.
Our current system is
designed to enrich the bankers and get everyone
else into debt.
And
is that not exactly what has happened?
Taking the creation of money away
from the bankers would have some
tremendous advantages. A recent article
<http://www.telegraph.co.uk/finance/comment/9623863/IMFs-epic-plan-to-conjure-away-debt-and-dethrone-bankers.html>
by renowned financial journalist Ambrose Evans-Pritchard described some
of these benefits...
{quote}
One could slash private debt by 100pc
of GDP, boost growth, stabilize
prices, and dethrone bankers all at the same
time. It could be done
cleanly and painlessly, by legislative command, far
more quickly than
anybody imagined.
The conjuring trick is to replace
our system of private bank-created
money -- roughly 97pc of the money supply
-- with state-created money.
We return to the historical norm, before
Charles II placed control of
the money supply in private hands with the
English Free Coinage Act of 1666.
Specifically, it means an assault on
"fractional reserve banking". If
lenders are forced to put up 100pc reserve
backing for deposits, they
lose the exorbitant privilege of creating money
out of thin air.
The nation regains sovereign control over the money
supply. There are no
more banks runs, and fewer boom-bust credit
cycles.
{end}
http://www.telegraph.co.uk/finance/comment/9623863/IMFs-epic-plan-to-conjure-away-debt-and-dethrone-bankers.html
So
why don't we go to such a system immediately?
Well, the transition to
such a system would undoubtedly be a major shock
to the global financial
system, and most people try to avoid significant
short-term pain even if
there are tremendous long-term benefits.
More importantly, however, is
that the bankers have a tremendous amount
of power in our society today, and
they would move heaven and earth to
keep a debt-free monetary system from
ever being implemented.
You see, the influence of the bankers is not just
limited to the big
banks. Our largest financial institutions (and the people
who own them)
also have large ownership stakes in the vast majority of the
big Fortune
500 corporations. In essence, the big banks are at the very
pinnacle of
"the establishment" in the United States and in almost every
other major
country in the western world.
And the vast majority of
all political campaigns are funded by "the
establishment". It takes an
enormous amount of money to win campaigns
these days, and most politicians
are extremely hesitant to bite the
hands of those that feed them.
So
don't expect any changes to happen overnight.
One proposal that has
actually been put forward in Congress is to cancel
all of the government
debt that the Federal Reserve is currently
holding. Right now, the Fed is
holding more than 1.6 trillion dollars of
U.S. government
debt...
That would seem to make a lot of sense. That would immediately
wipe more
than 1.6 trillion dollars from the U.S. national debt without any
real
harm being done.
But "the establishment" would be horrified if
such a thing happened, so
I wouldn't anticipate it happening any time
soon.
Hopefully we can get the American people (along with people all
over the
globe) educated about these things so that we can start to get
millions
of people pushing for change.
A debt-free monetary system is
superior to a debt-based monetary system
in so many ways.
For
example, if the U.S. government directly spent debt-free money into
circulation, it could conceivably never need to borrow a single dollar
ever again. If the government wanted to spend more money than it brought
in, it would simply print it up and spend it.
Of course the big
danger with that would be inflation. That is why it
would be imperative for
there to be a hard cap on what the government
could spend. For example, you
could set the cap on spending by the
federal government at 20 percent of
GDP. That way we would never end up
looking like the
<http://theeconomiccollapseblog.com/archives/quantitative-easing-did-not-work-for-the-weimar-republic-either>
Weimar Republic.
And the current federal debt could be paid down a
little at a time using
newly created debt-free dollars. This would have to
be done slowly to
keep inflation under control, but it could be
done.
That way we would not hand a
<http://theeconomiccollapseblog.com/archives/55-facts-about-the-debt-and-u-s-government-finances-that-every-american-voter-should-know>
16 trillion dollar debt to our children and our grandchildren. We
created this mess so we should clean it up.
Theoretically you could
also do away with the federal income tax if you
wanted to. Personally, I
would like to see the federal government be
funded to a large degree
<http://theeconomiccollapseblog.com/archives/obama-and-romney-both-favor-a-one-world-economic-system-that-kills-american-jobs>
by tariffs on foreign goods. That would also have the side benefit of
bringing millions of jobs back into the United States.
Our system of
income tax collection is just so incredibly inefficient.
It costs us mind
boggling amounts of time and money. Just consider the
following stats
<http://theeconomiccollapseblog.com/archives/24-outrageous-facts-about-taxes-in-the-united-states-that-will-blow-your-mind>
from one of my previous articles...
1 - The U.S. tax code is now
<http://www.taxfoundation.org/press/show/28121.html>
3.8 million words
long. If you took all of William Shakespeare's works and
collected them
together, the entire collection would only be about 900,000
words long.
2 - According to the National Taxpayers Union, U.S. taxpayers
spend
<http://www.ntu.org/news-and-issues/taxes/tax-reform/complexity.html>
more than 7.6 billion hours complying with federal tax requirements.
Imagine what our society would look like if all that time was spent on
more economically profitable activities.
3 - 75 years ago, the
instructions for Form 1040 were two pages long.
Today, they are
<http://www.smartmoney.com/taxes/income/10-things-i-hate-about-tax-day-1334094821191/#printMode>
189 pages long.
4 - There have been <http://www.taxfoundation.org/press/show/28121.html>
4,428 changes to the tax code over the last decade. It is incredibly
costly to change tax software, tax manuals and tax instruction booklets
for all of those changes.
5 - According to the National Taxpayers
Union, the IRS currently has
<http://www.ntu.org/news-and-issues/taxes/tax-reform/complexity.html>
1,999 different publications, forms, and instruction sheets that you can
download from the IRS website.
6 - Our tax system has become so
complicated that it is almost
impossible to file your taxes correctly. For
example, back in 1998 Money
Magazine had
<http://www.ntu.org/news-and-issues/taxes/tax-reform/complexity.html>
46
different tax professionals complete a tax return for a hypothetical
household. All 46 of them came up with a different result.
7 - In
2009, PC World had five of the most popular tax preparation
software
websites prepare a tax return for a hypothetical household. All
five of them
came up
<http://www.ntu.org/news-and-issues/taxes/tax-reform/complexity.html>
with a different result.
8 - The IRS spends
<http://www.9news.com/money/taxes/29093/301/Random-facts-about-taxes-to-ease-what-may-be-a-painful-day>
$2.45 for every $100 that it collects in taxes.
For long stretches of
our history the United States did not have any
income tax, and during those
times we thrived. It is entirely
conceivable that we could return to such a
system.
At this point, the wealthy have become absolute masters at hiding
their
wealth from taxation. According to the IMF, a total of 18 trillion
dollars is currently being hidden in offshore banks. What we are doing
right now produces very inequitable results and it is not working.
<http://theeconomiccollapseblog.com/archives/the-global-elite-are-hiding-18-trillion-dollars-in-offshore-banks>
In
many ways, inflation would be a much fairer "tax" than the income tax
because inflation taxes each dollar equally. Nobody would be able to
cheat the system.
But if people really love the IRS and the federal
income tax, we could
keep them under a debt-free money system. I just happen
to think that
the IRS and the federal income tax are both really bad ideas
that have
never served the interests of the American people.
In any
event, hopefully you can see that there is a much broader range
of solutions
to our problems than the two major political parties have
been presenting to
us.
We do not have to allow the banks to create our money.
The
federal government does not have to go into more debt.
We don't actually
need the Federal Reserve.
There are alternatives to the federal income
tax and the IRS.
Yes, it is very true that no system would be perfect.
But clearly the
path that we are on is only going to lead
<http://theeconomiccollapseblog.com/archives/unsustainable>
to disaster.
U.S. government finances are
<http://theeconomiccollapseblog.com/archives/55-facts-about-the-debt-and-u-s-government-finances-that-every-american-voter-should-know>
a complete and total nightmare, and this mountain of debt that we have
accumulated is going to absolutely destroy us if we allow it to.
So
somebody out there should be proposing a fundamental change in
direction for
our financial system.
Unfortunately, our politicians are just proposing
more of the same, and
we all know where that is going to lead.
(12)
Ambrose Evans-Pritchard: IMF's epic plan to conjure away debt and
dethrone
bankers
http://www.telegraph.co.uk/finance/comment/9623863/IMFs-epic-plan-to-conjure-away-debt-and-dethrone-bankers.html
IMF's
epic plan to conjure away debt and dethrone bankers
So there is a magic
wand after all. A revolutionary paper by the
International Monetary Fund
claims that one could eliminate the net
public debt of the US at a stroke,
and by implication do the same for
Britain, Germany, Italy, or
Japan.
By Ambrose Evans-Pritchard
2:31PM BST 21 Oct
2012
One could slash private debt by 100pc of GDP, boost growth,
stabilize
prices, and dethrone bankers all at the same time. It could be
done
cleanly and painlessly, by legislative command, far more quickly than
anybody imagined.
The conjuring trick is to replace our system of
private bank-created
money -- roughly 97pc of the money supply -- with
state-created money.
We return to the historical norm, before Charles II
placed control of
the money supply in private hands with the English Free
Coinage Act of
1666.
Specifically, it means an assault on "fractional
reserve banking". If
lenders are forced to put up 100pc reserve backing for
deposits, they
lose the exorbitant privilege of creating money out of thin
air.
The nation regains sovereign control over the money supply. There
are no
more banks runs, and fewer boom-bust credit cycles. Accounting
legerdemain will do the rest. That at least is the argument.
Some
readers may already have seen the IMF study, by Jaromir Benes and
Michael
Kumhof, which came out in August and has begun to acquire a cult
following
around the world.
Entitled "The Chicago Plan Revisited", it revives the
scheme first put
forward by professors Henry Simons and Irving Fisher in
1936 during the
ferment of creative thinking in the late
Depression.
Irving Fisher thought credit cycles led to an unhealthy
concentration of
wealth. He saw it with his own eyes in the early 1930s as
creditors
foreclosed on destitute farmers, seizing their land or buying it
for a
pittance at the bottom of the cycle.
The farmers found a way of
defending themselves in the end. They muscled
together at "one dollar
auctions", buying each other's property back for
almost nothing. Any
carpet-bagger who tried to bid higher was beaten to
a pulp.
Benes and
Kumhof argue that credit-cycle trauma - caused by private
money creation -
dates deep into history and lies at the root of debt
jubilees in the ancient
religions of Mesopotian and the Middle East.
Harvest cycles led to
systemic defaults thousands of years ago, with
forfeiture of collateral, and
concentration of wealth in the hands of
lenders. These episodes were not
just caused by weather, as long
thought. They were amplified by the effects
of credit.
The Athenian leader Solon implemented the first known Chicago
Plan/New
Deal in 599 BC to relieve farmers in hock to oligarchs enjoying
private
coinage. He cancelled debts, restituted lands seized by creditors,
set
floor-prices for commodities (much like Franklin Roosevelt), and
consciously flooded the money supply with state-issued "debt-free"
coinage.
The Romans sent a delegation to study Solon's reforms 150 years
later
and copied the ideas, setting up their own fiat money system under Lex
Aternia in 454 BC.
It is a myth - innocently propagated by the great
Adam Smith - that
money developed as a commodity-based or gold-linked means
of exchange.
Gold was always highly valued, but that is another story.
Metal-lovers
often conflate the two issues.
Anthropological studies
show that social fiat currencies began with the
dawn of time. The Spartans
banned gold coins, replacing them with iron
disks of little intrinsic value.
The early Romans used bronze tablets.
Their worth was entirely determined by
law - a doctrine made explicit by
Aristotle in his Ethics - like the dollar,
the euro, or sterling today.
Some argue that Rome began to lose its
solidarity spirit when it allowed
an oligarchy to develop a private
silver-based coinage during the Punic
Wars. Money slipped control of the
Senate. You could call it Rome's
shadow banking system. Evidence suggests
that it became a machine for
elite wealth accumulation.
Unchallenged
sovereign or Papal control over currencies persisted
through the Middle Ages
until England broke the mould in 1666. Benes and
Kumhof say this was the
start of the boom-bust era.
One might equally say that this opened the
way to England's agricultural
revolution in the early 18th Century, the
industrial revolution soon
after, and the greatest economic and
technological leap ever seen. But
let us not quibble.
The original
authors of the Chicago Plan were responding to the Great
Depression. They
believed it was possible to prevent the social havoc
caused by wild swings
from boom to bust, and to do so without crimping
economic
dynamism.
The benign side-effect of their proposals would be a switch
from
national debt to national surplus, as if by magic. "Because under the
Chicago Plan banks have to borrow reserves from the treasury to fully
back liabilities, the government acquires a very large asset vis-à-vis
banks. Our analysis finds that the government is left with a much lower,
in fact negative, net debt burden."
The IMF paper says total
liabilities of the US financial system -
including shadow banking - are
about 200pc of GDP. The new reserve rule
would create a windfall. This would
be used for a "potentially a very
large, buy-back of private debt", perhaps
100pc of GDP.
While Washington would issue much more fiat money, this
would not be
redeemable. It would be an equity of the commonwealth, not
debt.
The key of the Chicago Plan was to separate the "monetary and
credit
functions" of the banking system. "The quantity of money and the
quantity of credit would become completely independent of each
other."
Private lenders would no longer be able to create new deposits
"ex
nihilo". New bank credit would have to be financed by retained
earnings.
"The control of credit growth would become much more
straightforward
because banks would no longer be able, as they are today, to
generate
their own funding, deposits, in the act of lending, an
extraordinary
privilege that is not enjoyed by any other type of business,"
says the
IMF paper.
"Rather, banks would become what many erroneously
believe them to be
today, pure intermediaries that depend on obtaining
outside funding
before being able to lend."
The US Federal Reserve
would take real control over the money supply for
the first time, making it
easier to manage inflation. It was precisely
for this reason that Milton
Friedman called for 100pc reserve backing in
1967. Even the great free
marketeer implicitly favoured a clamp-down on
private money.
The
switch would engender a 10pc boost to long-arm economic output.
"None of
these benefits come at the expense of diminishing the core
useful functions
of a private financial system."
Simons and Fisher were flying blind in
the 1930s. They lacked the modern
instruments needed to crunch the numbers,
so the IMF team has now done
it for them -- using the `DSGE' stochastic
model now de rigueur in high
economics, loved and hated in equal
measure.
The finding is startling. Simons and Fisher understated their
claims. It
is perhaps possible to confront the banking plutocracy head
without
endangering the economy.
Benes and Kumhof make large claims.
They leave me baffled, to be honest.
Readers who want the technical details
can make their own judgement by
studying the text here.
The IMF duo
have supporters. Professor Richard Werner from Southampton
University - who
coined the term quantitative easing (QE) in the 1990s
-- testified to
Britain's Vickers Commission that a switch to
state-money would have major
welfare gains. He was backed by the
campaign group Positive Money and the
New Economics Foundation.
The theory also has strong critics. Tim Congdon
from International
Monetary Research says banks are in a sense already being
forced to
increase reserves by EU rules, Basel III rules, and gold-plated
variants
in the UK. The effect has been to choke lending to the private
sector.
He argues that is the chief reason why the world economy remains
stuck
in near-slump, and why central banks are having to cushion the shock
with QE.
"If you enacted this plan, it would devastate bank profits
and cause a
massive deflationary disaster. There would have to do `QE
squared' to
offset it," he said.
The result would be a huge shift in
bank balance sheets from private
lending to government securities. This
happened during World War Two,
but that was the anomalous cost of defeating
Fascism.
To do this on a permanent basis in peace-time would be to change
in the
nature of western capitalism. "People wouldn't be able to get money
from
banks. There would be huge damage to the efficiency of the economy," he
said.
Arguably, it would smother freedom and enthrone a Leviathan
state. It
might be even more irksome in the long run than rule by
bankers.
Personally, I am a long way from reaching an conclusion in this
extraordinary debate. Let it run, and let us all fight until we flush
out the arguments.
One thing is sure. The City of London will have
great trouble earning
its keep if any variant of the Chicago Plan ever gains
wide support.
No comments:
Post a Comment
Note: Only a member of this blog may post a comment.