The Finance Policy of Nazi Germany: Feder, Schacht and Hitler
Newsletter published on 16 November 2014
This
material is at http://mailstar.net/Feder-Schacht-Hitler.doc
(1)
The Finance Policy of Nazi Germany: Feder, Schacht and Hitler
(2) Hitler
sided with Schacht, sidelined Feder under Schmitt, an
Insurance
magnate
(3) Hitler repudiates Feder, before gaining power, in HITLER
SPEAKS
(4) Schacht battled against Feder; MEFO bills paid interest - Stephen
Zarlenga
(5) British Empire left the Gold Standard by 1931
(6)
Gold-holding US & Britain destabilized Germany's "Fiat" economy -
Robert
de Fremery
(1) The Finance Policy of Nazi Germany: Feder, Schacht and
Hitler
- by Peter Myers, November 16, 2014
The German Workers Party
was a socialist party founded by Gottfried
Feder, Anton Drexler and Karl
Harer. Hitler joined it and took it over,
renaming it the
NSDAP.
From Feder, Hitler learned that Governments do not need Gold to
operate
an economy. As long as there are workers and resources, the economy
can
operate on a "Fiat" basis. The Central Bank can create as much money as
is needed to fund employment, infrastructure and social programs. In
this respect, Rauschning was wrong and Hitler was right. Whereas
Rauschning argued that such money-creation would be inflationary, Hitler
insisted that he would control prices and wages, to stop it; and that is
what happened, the same as in the Soviet Union.
However, Hitler did
not nationalize private property, as happened in the
Soviet Union. He simply
placed control over private business in the
hands of a managerial
bureaucracy, subject to the Government. John
Burnham's book The Managerial
Revolution was the second book about the
similarity between Soviet and Nazi
management of the economy. Burnham
was a Trotskyist who became a leading
anti-Communist, and later worked
for the CIA.
Burnham's book was not
the first on that theme. It had been preceded by
one other book, The
Bureaucratisation of the World, by Bruno Rizzi
(1939). He was also a
Trotskyist, who praised the Nazi economic management:
http://www.marxists.org/archive/rizzi/bureaucratisation/index.htm
Trotsky
himself commented on this book:
http://www.marxists.org/archive/trotsky/1939/09/ussr-war.htm
The
theme was later taken up by Friedrich von Hayek in his book The Road
to
Serfdom. He argued that the New Deal, and by extension the postwar
socialist
regimes in Britain and Australia, were a slippery slope that
would lead to
Totalitarianism. This was the justification for
Thatcherism and
Reaganomics.
There are a lot of silly debates about whether Hitler wanted
war. But
that's the wrong question. The right question is, "Did Hitler want
an
Empire?" And the answer to that question is unequivally Yes. It's just
that he preferred it to fall into his lap, without fighting, as much as
possible.
Hitler makes his imperial ambition clear in Mein Kampf. It
is not for
nothing that he visited the grave of Napoleon.
Stalin, not
being stupid, prepared for war too. Viktor Suvorov points
out that, just
before Hitler attacked Stalin, Stalin had been getting
ready to attack
Hitler. Both sides had dismantled their defensive
positions. There was going
to be a war between them; the only question
was who would attack first. The
lesson was not lost on Moshe Dayan in 1967.
Stephen Zarlenga's book The
Lost Science Of Money gives an excellent
account of Nazi finance policy. He
explains how Feder was sidelined by
Schacht (and Hitler). MEFO bills paid
interest (4.5%), so were not
debt-free money like Lincoln's Greenbacks - the
sort Feder had advocated.
Feder's problem was that he knew the theory of
money, but had no
practical experience of, say, running a bank. If you want
to learn a new
skill - welding metal or grafting trees - the theory is
insufficient;
you must get practical experience too. Without that, you're
nothing.
That was the difference bwteeen Schacht and Feder.
Zarlenga
quotes Robert de Fremery to the effect that the Gold-using
countries were
operating a financial war against Germany. The British
Empire had left the
Gold Standard by 1931, but was producing half the
world's Gold. Roosevelt
took the US off the Gold Standard in 1933, but
the $ remained Gold-backed at
$35 per ounce. These two powers did not
take kindly to Germany showing that
you could bypass Gold altogether.
However, even if that was a
contributing cause to the war, Hitler's
imperial ambitions were a greater
cause. His racial antagonism to Slavs
was a throwback from the First World
War, during which Germany had
conquered Ukraine and the other western
provinces of Russia. Hitler
wanted that territory back. Just as the British
called the Germans
"Huns" during that war, the Germans belittled the Slavs.
It's was the
basis of Hitler's genocidal policies towards them.
(2)
Hitler sided with Schacht, sidelined Feder under Schmitt, an
Insurance
magnate
http://spartacus-educational.com/GERfeder.htm
Gottfried
Feder
[...] Throughout the 1920s Feder was a leader of the
anti-capitalist
wing of the Nazi Party. In 1924 he was elected to the
Reichstag. He put
forward his views in Das Programm der NSDAP (1931), Kampf
gegen die
Hochfinannz (1933) and Die Juden (1933) where he expressed his
anti-semitic views.
As Feder held the important post of chairman of
the party's economic
council, his anti-capitalist views led to a decline in
financial support
from Germany's major industrialists. Hjalmar Schacht
warned Hitler that
Feder's economic planning apparatus would ruin the German
economy. After
pressure from figures such as Albert Voegler, Gustav Krupp,
Friedrich
Flick, Fritz Thyssen and Emile Kirdorf, Hitler decided to move the
party
away from Feder's left-wing economic theories.
When Adolf
Hitler became chancellor in 1933 he appointed Feder as
Under-Secretary at
the Ministry of Economics. Feder was disappointed
that he had not been given
a more senior position. Konrad Heiden pointed
out that Feder also had to
serve under someone who completely opposed
his economic policies: "The post
of under-secretary was an humiliating
position ... His new superior was
almost a stranger to the party, but
familiar to the stock exchange... he was
Doctor Karl Schmitt, general
director of the largest German insurance
company. A more pronounced
representative of rapacious capital would have
been hard to find;
Schmitt had spent his life lending money and collecting
interest; he had
literally bought his way into the National Socialist
Movement by giving
the party generous aid in hard times."
Feder
continued to campaign for nationalization, profit-sharing, the
abolition of
unearned incomes and the "thraldom of interest". Hitler
refused to do
this.
(3) Hitler repudiates Feder, before gaining power, in HITLER
SPEAKS
HITLER SPEAKS: Conversations of 1932-34 recorded by Hermann
Rauschning
http://mailstar.net/Hitler-Speaks-Rauschning.doc
{p.
29} THE PLAN IN THE DRAWER
Hitler's questions as to the position in
Danzig led us directly to the
economic problems. [...] the party's two
economic and technical experts,
the civil engineers Feder and Lawaczek,
whose curious theories,
propounded in "intellectual gatherings," invited the
ridicule of
economists and caused acute embarrassment to all intelligent
party
members. I therefore asked Hitler, whose relations with Feder were not
at the time known to me, about the possibility of financing the economic
program. I could not see, I remarked, that Feder's theory was anything
but financing by means of an inflation.
"How do you mean?" said
Hitler, eyeing me with displeasure. "I am not
worrying about financing our
program. You may safely leave that to me.
As long as speculators are kept
out, there are no difficulties."
"But," I ventured to interpose, "it will
not be possible to keep prices
stable if the creation of employment is
financed thus. Feder's money
theory will also have an inflationary
effect."
"You get inflation if you want inflation," Hitler retorted
angrily.
"Inflation is lack of discipline - lack of discipline in the
buyers, and
lack of discipline in the sellers. I will see to it that prices
remain
stable. That is what my S.A. is for. Woe to the men who raise prices!
We
need no legal instruments for that. It will be done by the party alone.
You shall see— if our S.A . once clean up a shop, such things will not
happen a second time."
{p. 30} "Besides," Hitler continued, "I do not
worry about the theories
of Feder and Lawaczek. I have a gift for tracing
back all theories to
their roots in reality. I have nothing to do with
pipe-dreams. You need
not take this man Feder and his associates literally,
even though
officially the party does so. Let them talk as they please. When
I am in
power, I shall see to it that they do no mischief. If these men
cause
confusion, Forster, you will no longer allow them to speak. These
people
cannot think simply. Everything has got to be complicated. I have the
gift of simplification, and then everything works itself out.
Difficulties exist only in the imagination!"
Hitler's repudiation of
Feder was at that time new to me. It was
interesting as an indication of
Hitler's supremacy over his entourage. [...]
(4) Schacht battled against
Feder; MEFO bills paid interest - Stephen
Zarlenga
The Lost Science
Of Money
by Stephen Zarlenga
American Monetary Institute,
2002
{p. 590} HITLER TAKEN BY FEDER'S MONETARY VIEWS
When World
War I ended, a destitute Adolf Hitler was given an assignment
by Gennan Army
intelligence to watch a tiny political group called the
German Workers
Party. He attended a small meeting where Gottfried
Feder's monetary views
made a very deep impression on him.
The basis of Feder's ideas was that
the state should create and control
its money supply through a nationalized
central bank rather than have it
created by privately owned banks, to whom
interest would have to be
paid. From this view was derived the conclusion
that finance had
enslaved the population by usurping the nation's control of
money.
Feder's views could easily have originated from the work of German
monetary theorists such as George Knapp, whose book The State Theory of
Money (1905) is still one of the classics in the monetary area.
[...]
{p. 591} Near the end of that book, Knapp casually mentions how
German
monetary theorists of his day and earlier would study and discuss
American monetary theories. Thus the ultimate source of Feder's
viewpoint may have been the ideas of the American Greenback movement of
the 1870s.
Unfortunately, Feder's monetary views were mixed up with
an all
consuming anti-Semitism. [...]
{p. 592} SCHACHT BATTLES
FEDER
When the National Socialists came to power, Schacht was reappointed
head
of the Reichsbank, partly to reassure German big business and foreign
bankers. Schacht battled against Feder's un-orthodox monetary
views:
"Nationalization of banks, abolition of bondage to interest
payments,
and introduction of state Giro 'Feder'money, those were the high
sounding phrases of a pressure group which aimed at the overthrow of
our
{p. 593} money and banking system. To keep this nonsense in check I
called a bankers' council which made suggestions for tighter supervision
and control over the banks. These suggestions were codified in the law
of 1934 ... In the course of several discussions I succeeded in
dissuading Hitler from putting into practice the most foolish and
dangerous of the ideas on banking and currency harbored by his party
colleagues." [...]
FEDER LOST
Feder quickly lost the battle
with Schacht and the German business
establishment. [...]
Feder was
"put out to pasture" by the National Socialists, serving as an
under
secretary in the Ministry of Economic Affairs. He was later
transferred to
commissioner for land settlement, and then completely
sidetracked as a
lecturer at the Technische Hochschule in Berlin.
{p. 594} BUT "FEDER
MONEY" WORKED WELL
Hitler and the National Socialists came to power on
January 30, 1933.
Germany's foreign exchange and gold reserves had dropped
from 2.6
billion marks in late 1929, down to 409 million in late 1933, and
to
only 83 million marks in late 1934. According to classical economic
theory Germany was broke and would have to borrow, but Germany was to
demonstrate that "classical" monetary theory is not very
accurate.
This period of German monetary history has received far too
little
attention in English. On May 1, 1933 Hitler outlined the Ist
Reinhardt
Program - a four-year plan to end unemployment by attacking it on
several fronts:
• Spending I billion marks worth of "employment
creation bills."
• Tax benefits for industry, agriculture, and the
employment of domestic
help.
• Marriage bonus loans up to 1,000 marks
and
• Government control of the money and capital markets, under
Schacht.
Although elements of this program had already started under the
predecessor Von Papen and Schleicher Regimes, they had not been all out
efforts against unemployment.
On May 31st, the German government
decided to issue I billion marks of
short term public works bills,
designated to pay for specific
infrastructure projects:
"These were
negotiable certificates paid out to employers who under-took
projects of
replacement or maintenance projects. Anyone who equipped a
factory with new
machines or who had his house repainted 34 could
finance his operations with
these work drafts...," wrote Heiden.
These bills paid about 4 1/2%
interest, and as they were taken into the
banking system, they were renewed
indefinitely, and made eligible for
rediscounting by the Reichsbank. This
means that they became part of the
underlying basis for the nation's money
supply, along with gold and
foreign exchange and long term Government
Bonds.3
The author has seen these bills referred to as "Feder money," and
as
"work drafts" (Arbeits-Schatzanwersungen). Schacht later referred to
MEFO bills, mentioning no connection with Feder.
Many of the bills
never found their way to the Reichsbank, since the
interest they paid was an
incentive for banks and others to hold onto
them. Roberts estimated that as
much as 15 billion marks worth of such
{p. 595} bills were issued. Heiden
made a lower estimate:
"All in all the public Treasury poured out
approximately 3 billion marks
... for projects which according to the view
hitherto prevailing (e.g.
Schacht's) in those times of crisis, were
senseless or at least
unnecessary ..."
Guillebaud also estimated an
upper limit of 15 billion marks of all
types of bills used to finance public
works in this period, but noted that:
"No exact figures exist for the
circulation of employment bills, but
they can be estimated with reasonable
accuracy at 1.2 billion RM at the
end of December 1933, and at 2.6 billion
RM a year later."
When the process started in 1933, Reichsbank holdings
of all such
instruments, including normal treasury issues, totaled 3.03
billion
marks. At the end of 1934 total holdings were 3.86 billion and at
the
end of 1936 there were 4.91 billion marks.39
Thus Germany did not
take the full step and create a German equivalent
to the American Greenback.
The Greenbacks themselves were money, had no
interest payments due on them
and did not add to any national debt.
These German infrastructure bills were
a form of debt certificate,
promising to pay money; they paid interest and
did add to Germany's
national debt.
But this very close money
substitute still had dramatic effects.
They were an excellent way to get
purchasing power into the hands of
newly employed workers. Unemployment had
been at six million in 1933,
and was down to around one million at the end
of 1936.
Furthermore, whereas the American Greenbacks had been spent
mostly on
warfare and destruction, the "Feder money" had gone almost
entirely into
public works projects, especially the construction of new
middle class
housing. In 1934 there were 283,995 dwellings built com-pared
to 141,265
in 1932. Then there were the thousands of kilometers of Autobahn
construction.
Thus it can be argued that the cause of Hitler's
immense popularity
among Germans was that he temporarily rescued Germany
from English
economic theory. For while these activities strongly benefited
the
German middle and lower classes, they were of great concern to some
foreign bankers. Although Germany's move away from gold was more a
matter of necessity than choice, it still threatened "vested interests."
Robert de Fremery quotes from the June 1940 National City Bank Bulletin
which admitted that:
{p. 596} "not only the United States but
other countries as well have
large vested interests in gold. The British
Empire alone accounts for
nearly half of the gold output of the world, and
in many other countries
gold is an important national asset. These countries
would not took with
favor upon the displacement of gold as a monetary metal;
and even in the
event of political changes resulting from the war these
vested interests
will remain, though possibly shifted to other national
jurisdictions."
The reader will notice that these "vested interest"
countries were the
ones that warred with "goldless" Germany. De Fremery
thought this could
have been one of the causes of the Second World War.
However, that
decision may have been made earlier, and itself led to Germany
being
without gold. Perhaps she was expected to borrow gold internationally,
and that would have meant external control over her domestic policies.
Her decision to use alternatives to gold, would mean that the
international financiers would be unable to exercise this control
through the international gold standard, as described in Chapter 22, and
this may have led to controlling Germany through warfare
instead.
SCHACHT ATE SOME CROW OVER FEDER MONEY
Schacht clearly
had to "eat crow" and swallow his own words as regards
the new monetary
issues that he earlier condemned. Thirty years later he
justified his change
of theory:
"... it was repeatedly asked whether the success of the MEFO
bill scheme
did not mean that whenever there was a shortage of capital
savings one
could compensate by replacing such capital savings with credits
granted
by the central bank, and thus by money specially granted for the
purpose. The English economist J.M. Keynes has delt with the problem
theoretically, and MEFO transactions prove the practical applicability
of such an idea."
But Schacht insisted that certain conditions must
exist. There had been
no stocks of raw materials; factories were empty;
machines were idle and
6 '/2million willing men were unemployed: "The
capital which could be
expected to result from such developments (putting
men to work) was used
in advance to grant credit through the MEFO
transactions.'"
SCHACHT FIRED OVER THESE MATTERS
These bills were
used from 1934 to 1938. Schacht relates how he got
himself fired by refusing
to continue renewing the bills:
"In January 1939, the Reichsbank handed
Hitler a memorandum in which it
indicated its refusal to grant the Reich any
further credits. The
{p. 597} consequences were drastic. On January 19, I
was dismissed from
my office as President ... on the following day Hitler
issued an edict
which ordered the Reichsbank to grant the Reich all credits
for which
the Fuhrer asked. It is true the MEFO bills were now honored when
they
came due, but only with the inflated money produced by the printing
presses. The second inflation had begun."
Schacht's firing was not
made public for five months. His refusal to
continue financing the Reich was
probably what saved him at Nuremberg. [...]
{p. 599} SCHACHT FINALLY SEES
THE LIGHT
Schacht began his banking career as a believer in the gold
standard, the
system then used in England and America. But by 1967, it
appears he had
come to agree with some of Gottfried Feder's "unorthodox"
monetary views:
"Modern paper money, the banknote is backed by its
creator, the state ..."
Thus Schacht made a monetary pilgrimage similar
to that of Thomas
Jefferson, Alexander Del Mar, and many others, away from
the primitive
commodity view of money as metal, to an awareness of the
"nominal," fiat
nature of money as being based in law.
"The granting
of credit is unthinkable without a central bank. No
central bank can be
allowed to act against the government of the
country. The government is over
the central Bank ... A central bank
cannot allow any competition," wrote
Schacht.
But then Schacht qualified this, stating that a higher law above
both
the government and the central bank is the constancy of the value of
money. Stated in a more political manner, he is saying is that above
both the central bank and the government is the bondholder.
Schacht
insisted that only by keeping the currency stable could the
small savers
ever have a chance to accumulate substantial savings. He
rejected their use
of investments as indoctrinating them into gambling.
However, the use of
well managed instruments such as balanced mutual
funds can now overcome this
objection. And after all, when unemployment
caused by an overly restrictive
monetary policy strikes, it is the small
saver who generally suffers
most.
In Summary
An examination of the German hyperinflation of
1923 shows that the
simplistic anti-governmental interpretation of the
economists and
financiers is without basis. Nearly the opposite of what they
contend,
was true: the hyperinflation followed the complete privatization of
the
German central bank and elimination of governmental influence on
it.
Again it was governmental action - this time the German govemment -
not
private bankers - that rescued the monetary situation.
(5)
British Empire left the Gold Standard by 1931
{but the British Empire
continued to produce half the world's Gold after
that - see next
item}
http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Gold_standard
In
September 19, 1931, speculative attacks on the pound forced Britain
to
abandon the gold standard. [...] The British benefited from this
departure.
They could now use monetary policy to stimulate the economy.
Australia and
New Zealand had already left the standard and Canada
quickly followed suit.
[...]
Some economic historians, such as Barry Eichengreen, blame the gold
standard of the 1920s for prolonging the economic depression which
started in 1929 and lasted for about a decade.[28] Adherence to the gold
standard prevented the Federal Reserve from expanding the money supply
to stimulate the economy, fund insolvent banks and fund government
deficits that could "prime the pump" for an expansion. Once off the gold
standard, it became free to engage in such money creation. The gold
standard limited the flexibility of the central banks' monetary policy
by limiting their ability to expand the money supply.
This page was
last modified on 16 October 2014 at 22:40.
(6) Gold-holding US &
Britain destabilized Germany's "Fiat" economy -
Robert de Fremery
http://www.cooperativeindividualism.org/fremery-robert-de_money-and-freedom-1955-07.html
Money
and Freedom
An Application of Natural Laws to the Problem of Money -- The
Disastrous
Economic and Political Consequences of our Unsound Monetary
System -- A
Suggested Remedy
Robert de Fremery
[CHAPTER VII:
"Shall We Return To A Gold Standard -- Now?"]
[...] There is also good
reason for believing that some of the friction
existing between countries
prior to the outbreak of the second world war
may have had its roots in the
gold-credit mechanism. In this connection,
the following quotation from the
National City Bank Bulletin deserves
careful scrutiny:
"A second
important reason why gold is unlikely to lose its value is
that not only the
United States, but other countries as well have large
vested interests in
gold. The British Empire alone accounts for nearly
half the gold output of
the world, and in many other countries gold
production is an important
national asset. These countries would not
look with favor upon the
displacement of gold as a monetary metal; and
even in the event of political
changes resulting from the war these
vested interests will remain, though
possibly shifted to other national
jurisdictions." (p. 70) (Italics
added)
It will be remembered that Germany had made an effort to get out
from
under the gold standard during the 1930s. She had carried on quite an
experiment with "fiat" money. (See quotation from Dr. B. M. Anderson,
Jr.). Now if the gold standard countries "would not look with favor upon
the displacement of gold as a monetary metal," it is reasonable to
suppose they had tried to hinder the success of Germany's experiment.
And the obvious way to hinder the success of that experiment would have
been to discount Germany's currency in such a way as to discourage
businessmen in other countries from accepting that currency. That would
have forced the Germans to engage in barter agreements -- which is what
actually happened. And since barter is, at best, a long step backward in
the economic development of the world, it is reasonable to suppose that
the increasing tensions resulting from such unsatisfactory arrangements
would have been conducive to the outbreak of war.
It can be argued,
of course, that it was perfectly natural for the
bankers of the
gold-standard countries to discount Germany's currency if
it was not
redeemable in gold. That would have been in accordance with
the way the
international gold standard is supposed to work. But let's
face the fact
that such a system leads to friction between those
countries that wish to
keep the gold standard and those countries that
wish to free themselves from
the tyranny of the gold standard.
It can also be argued that Germany was
forced to barter because of her
fiat money -- the implication being that if
the gold standard were
abandoned by all countries, then all foreign trade
would have to be done
by barter arrangements. But that is not so. Germany
was forced to barter
because of the clash between the international gold
standard and
Germany's system of a national "fiat" money that was
independent of the
gold standard. If there were no international
gold-standard, there would
have been no clash and therefore no necessity for
barter. International
trade would have been regulated by mild changes in
exchange rates
reflecting changes in the supply of, and demand for, various
currencies
as determined by change in the volume of imports and exports of
the
countries concerned. Exchange rates would then always reflect
supply-and-demand relationships between imports and exports rather than
reflecting the degree to which currencies are convertible into gold. (A
fuller discussion of this subject is given later.)
So to those who
try to blame the breakdown of the gold-credit system on
wars, we have a
perfect right to say that there would be less tension in
the world, and more
genuine cooperation between countries, and therefore
less chance of wars
breaking out, if the gold-credit system were
abandoned by all
countries.
No comments:
Post a Comment
Note: Only a member of this blog may post a comment.